Figures
Abstract
This paper attempts to describe and explain the long-term evolution of wage inequality in imperial China, covering over two millennia from the Han dynasty to the Qing dynasty (202 BCE-1912 CE). Based on historical government records of official salaries, commodity prices, and agricultural productivity, we convert various forms of salaries to equivalent rice volumes and comparable salary benchmarks. Wage inequality is measured by salary ratios and (partial) Gini coefficients between official and peasant classes as well as within the official class. The inter-class wage inequality features an “inverted U-u” pattern—first rose before the Tang dynasty and then declined afterwards (the “inverted U” trends) with “inverted u” dynastic cycles. The intra-class wage inequality has a secular decline trend. We propose a unified framework incorporating technological, institutional, political, and social (TIPS) mechanisms to explain both long-term and short-term patterns. It is concluded that the technological mechanism dominated the rise of wage inequality, while the political mechanism (emperor-bureaucracy power tensions) drove the decline.
Citation: Wu Q, Tong G, Zhou P (2025) Long-term wage inequality in imperial China: From 202 BCE to 1912 CE. PLoS ONE 20(1): e0315627. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0315627
Editor: Shai Gordin, Ariel University, ISRAEL
Received: April 19, 2024; Accepted: November 27, 2024; Published: January 24, 2025
Copyright: © 2025 Wu et al. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.
Data Availability: All relevant data are within the paper and its Supporting Information files.
Funding: This study was supported by the General Project of the National Social Science Fund of China (Grant Number: 23BJY133). The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.
Competing interests: The authors have declared that no competing interests exist.
Introduction
The growth-inequality nexus is a prominent research interest among economists. A pioneering yet controversial view is the Kuznets hypothesis which proposes that inequality follows an inverted U-shaped curve as the economy transitions from an agrarian to an industrial society in modern growth [1]. Later studies extend the hypothesis to the premodern growth as a “super Kuznets curve” [2]. Some studies show support for such an inverted U relationship under certain conditions (e.g., [3,4]), while many others refute a clear relationship between productivity and inequality (e.g., [5–8]). As a salvage attempt, Milanovic argues that there may not be a single Kuznets curve for a given country but rather a series of Kuznets curves, or waves, responding to new technological revolutions [9]. This is known as the Kuznetsian view. However, the prevailing tendency in literature is to discard the Kuznets hypothesis as obsolete [10]. As Kuznets himself commented, the hypothesis is “perhaps 5 percent empirical information and 95 percent speculation, some of it possibly tainted by wishful thinking”.
The debate has nonetheless inspired numerous theories of the growth-inequality relationship such as innovation and technological changes [11,12], industrial structures [13,14], employment structures [15,16], characteristics of labor markets [17,18], urbanization [19], and globalization [20]. Specifically, Piketty and his coauthors challenged the reliance on technology in explaining inequality changes [21–23]. Based on evidence from France, Australia, Canada, Britain, and the US in the 20th century, they find that social norms (implicit rules) and institutional arrangements (explicit rules) in distribution (e.g., union) and redistribution (e.g., taxation) can play more important roles in shaping inequality [24–26]. Nevertheless, most studies are based on postwar evidence, and few have been devoted to long-term interdependence between growth and inequality over several centuries [25].
In contrast to the burgeoning literature on Unified Growth Theory [26,27], the advancement in “Unified Inequality Theory” is slow. One reason is the lack of reliable data on historical inequality. In contemporary society, income survey data can meet the demand to construct a comprehensive Gini coefficient. For pre-industrial society, social tables are sometimes used, but within-class inequalities cannot be well captured [28]. As a result, research is usually done for subperiods of history [29] and mainly in the west, e.g., Germany [30], France [31], Russia [32], Britain [33], and the US [34]. Dissimilar to Western countries, China has no continuously marketed wage data, just fragmentary records of official salaries [35] and construction laborers [36], so the research on inequality in China mainly concentrates on a particular dynasty [37]. To broaden the geographical and temporal scopes, this study compiles various historical records and provides useful benchmarks of wage inequality in imperial China. It covers an extensive period of 2,113 years, spanning from 202 BCE (the beginning of the Han dynasty) to 1912 CE (the end of the Qing dynasty).
China offers an interesting case for studying economic history due to its cultural continuity and geographical isolation [38]. A wealth of historical records on wages and prices has been meticulously documented as the Chinese civilization evolved over the past several millennia. Despite some changes in the Chinese language, the written form has remained largely stable, allowing any educated individuals in the 21st century to comprehend records written more than two thousand years ago. This linguistic continuity enables us to construct a long series of measures of wage inequality, a task that proves much more challenging in other countries. To facilitate exposition, Fig 1 lists all Chinese dynasties chronologically with historical events in the western civilization. It can be a helpful navigator for those who are not familiar with Chinese dynasties.
The empirical benchmarks on wage inequality are the first contribution of our paper. Based on historical records on official salaries, prices, and agricultural productivity, we measure wage inequality both between the rich (officials) and the poor (peasants) as well as among the rich. Admittedly, land rents and corrupt revenue lead to underestimation of official income, making our measure of wage inequality a lower bound of income inequality. In addition, our data cannot capture all aspects of inequality in imperial China due to the lack of records in every social class (e.g., seigniors, artisans, merchants, soldiers) and every region, so the wage ratios and Gini coefficients computed in this paper are a partial rather than a comprehensive measure of inequality. We argue that officials and peasants represent the majority of the rich and the poor, so the constructed measures based on the two social classes (“inter-class” inequality) allow us to portray, at the very least, a rough picture of inequality in imperial China. Overall, we find a gradual increase in wage inequality from the Han to the mid-Tang dynasty (about a millennium from 202 BCE-841 CE) and a decline from the late-Tang to the Qing dynasty (about a millennium from 841–1912 CE). The trends appear to be in line with the inverted U shape pattern. In addition to the long-term pattern, we also find a short-term pattern of “inverted u” dynastic cycles (the lowercase “u” is intentionally used for cycles and the uppercase “U” is used for trends). Therefore, the overall wage inequality features an inverted U-u pattern. By contrast, the wage inequality within officials (“intra-class” inequality) witnessed a secular decline over the two millennia, but with inverted u cycles.
The second contribution of our paper is theoretical. Building on the long-term series of (partial) wage inequality, we propose a unified framework to explain the evolution of inequality in a pre-industrial society. Our explanation combines the Kuznetsian productivity view with social, institutional, and political views. The initial increase in inequality was driven by technological improvements in agriculture [39], while the later decline was mainly due to political tensions. Changes in explicit rules (e.g., institutionalization of imperial exams) and implicit rules (e.g., Neo-Confucianism social norms) were embodiments of the emperor-bureaucracy tension. Specifically, Neo-Confucianism in the Song dynasties (from circa 12th century) introduced new moral principles discouraging individual economic pursuits while emphasizing the supreme authority of emperors. These new social norms were supported by emperors to strengthen their power and had permanent impacts to wage inequality [40]. Moreover, bottom-up uprisings, internal rebellions, and external wars resulted in lower wage inequality in later dynasties and in later phases of each dynasty because the military budget was prioritized over official salaries. The novelty of our paper is that long-term “inverted U trends” and short-term “inverted u cycles” can be explained using the same framework, which is even generalizable to the modern world.
This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the social and income hierarchies in imperial China. In Section 3, we describe our data and measures of wage inequality. Section 4 presents the results of wage inequality and identifies patterns of wage inequality. In Section 5, we propose a unified theoretical framework to explain the identified patterns and Section 6 concludes.
Social hierarchy and income ladder
Scheidel argues for a “Great Convergence” between the West and China that spanned the entire first millennium BCE and the first half of the first millennium CE, until a “Great Divergence” began to unfold from about the 6th century CE onward [41]. The Western civilization is characterized by a tradition of decentralized governance [42]. This tradition was inherited from ancient Greek city-states and developed under the Roman Empire (e.g., a balance of power among the Senate, magistrates, and provinces), the Middle Ages (e.g., shared power among central monarchs, feudal lords, and local nobility), the Renaissance and Enlightenment periods (e.g., philosophical ideas of individual rights, freedoms, and the social contract), and modern times (e.g., federal systems in the US, devolved governments in the UK, and the Subsidiarity Principle in the EU). In contrast, centralized governance is a prominent characteristic of eastern civilizations [43], notably exemplified by China [44] and Japan [45]. An intended outcome of the high concentration of power is a stable social hierarchy paired with a stable income distribution system founded in the Qin and Han dynasties [46].
The social hierarchy in ancient China has a long history originated in the Zhou dynasty (1046–221 BCE). It is represented by a top-down pyramid of power (Fig 2) with an isomorphic structure between family and government.
At the top of the pyramid is the emperor (the “Son of Heaven”, the supreme ruler, and the embodiment of authority), whose legitimacy is believed to be granted by Heaven. Directly below the emperor were aristocrats (nobles with hereditary status) and seigniors (sons of former emperors without legitimate claims to the throne). In early dynasties (e.g., Zhou, Han, Jin), they served as high-ranking officials, military commanders, and advisers to the emperor. In later dynasties, however, most of seigniors did not serve as officials due to increasing political tensions among imperial princes. For example, in the Ming dynasty, the number of seigniors grew very quickly because there was no limit on their fertility. Central and local governments financially supported them, so the fiscal burden also became very large when their population grew. We do not have accurate data for this social class, but their wage can be reasonably assumed to be close to the low-ranking officials.
Further down the hierarchy were the scholars, known as the Shi class, who were either sons of the aristocrats without hereditary status or talents from the lower class. They connected the upper and the lower classes, so they are in some sense the “middle class” in imperial China. Before the Sui dynasty, most scholars obtained their government positions through recommendations from aristocrats and other officials (“Ju Xiao Lian”). During the Sui dynasty, a new system of imperial civil service examinations (“Ke Ju”) was introduced, becoming the primary means of selecting officials from scholars and lower class. Once they obtained an official position, the rank of the position determined their authority, responsibility, and income. Besides, many grassroots officials did not have ranks (called “Li”). They were clerks responsible for maintaining records, handling paperwork, managing finances, and performing other administrative duties. In addition to serving within the bureaucratic system, scholars in ancient China had the option to pursue purely academic endeavors. They often established and managed Confucius academies where they taught younger scholars. Leaders of Neo-Confucianism, like Zhu Xi and Lu Jiuyuan, were prominent examples of such scholars. Although they were not government officials themselves, their schools of thought held significant political influence since many officials were their students.
At the bottom of the pyramid were peasants, artisans, merchants, and soldiers. In all households of emperors, aristocrats, scholars, and ordinary people, the eldest legitimate son usually inherited the title from his father, while other sons left the households with lower or no titles. The top-down power structure of the patriarchal hierarchy effectively determines the income ladder as the centralized system decides “who gets what”. The output, produced by the lower class but distributed by the upper class, forms a bottom-up flow of value. A higher social class on the income ladder receives higher income.
It is worth emphasizing that the social classes in early dynasties (prior to Sui) were largely frozen and usually could not be changed. For example, in the Qin and Han dynasties, a peasant was always a peasant, and his son was also a peasant. They could not freely choose to be a scholar, artisan, merchant, or soldier, and vice versa. Government officials were mainly selected from scholars and aristocrats. In other words, there was limited horizontal social mobility across occupations. Moreover, vertical social mobility across hierarchies was also restricted. For scholars (the Shi class), they must engage in fierce competition to ascend to higher ranks, occasionally to aristocratic titles. Only in exceptional cases can people from the lower class be promoted, e.g., a soldier with remarkable military achievements can be awarded an aristocratic title. Entrepreneurship was generally considered despicable in imperial China [47]. Most dynasties cherished the physiocratic model of economy that emphasized the importance of agriculture and restricted commercial activities. Social mobility in later dynasties (Sui, Tang, Song, Ming, and Qing) was significantly improved thanks to the “Ke Ju” system [48]. For example, if one had passed the imperial examination at the provincial level, he could become a middle-rank official. While the “Ke Ju” system improved intergenerational mobility, the evolution of social norms beginning in the Song dynasty may have restricted intragenerational mobility, as the rights of individuals were curtailed. This trend aligns with the findings of Yang & Zhou, who suggest that increasing inequality in this period was positively correlated with reduced intragenerational mobility (the Great Gatsby curve) [49].
According to historical fiscal records, officials constituted less than 1% of the total population in all dynasties. Officials received secured salaries from governments, much higher than peasants. They were the top earners in imperial China and their wage differentials significantly influence the wage inequality.
The official ranks had a steep hierarchical structure that resulted in substantial wage inequality among officials. Before the Sui dynasty, the ranking system distinguished 17–20 levels of officials. The highest-rank officials were paid 10,000 dan grains per year (hence the official rank was referred to as the Ten Thousand Dan), while the lowest-rank officials were only paid 100 dan grains per year (hence the official rank was referred to as One Hundred Dan). The term “dan”, also called picul or tam, was an ancient unit of weight (equal to 29.5–31 kilograms in the Han dynasty and 50 kilograms after the Song dynasty). From the Sui dynasty onward, the ranking system was reformed; officials were ranked from the lowest 9th Pin to the highest 1st Pin. The term “Pin” means rank in Chinese. The switch from the absolute rank (Dan) to the relative rank (Pin) can better accommodate productivity changes and make salary adjustments.
The two ranking systems are comparable. For example, county governors were usually ranked at the Six Hundred Dan before the Sui dynasty but were ranked at the 7th Pin in later dynasties. The lowest-rank 9th Pin was equivalent to the One Hundred Dan, and the highest-rank 1st Pin was equivalent to the Ten Thousand Dan. These ranks may have different terms, but the corresponding positions can be mapped.
Official salaries took various forms including grain, salt, fabrics, labor, land (rents), copper, silver, and paper money. Earlier dynasties usually paid officials with grains and coins, whereas later dynasties increasingly used monetary payment. During periods of warfare, governments often offered more diverse forms of payment, such as in the Southern & Northern dynasties when official salaries mainly took the form of fabrics, laborers, and lands (see Table 1). It is also worth emphasizing that these records were officially documented salaries which did not include hidden or corrupt revenues. Previous studies have shown that corruption in the Ming and Qing dynasties was more severe than early dynasties [50,51], so the measures based on these records are lower bounds of wage inequality.
Empirical methods
This section starts with a discussion of data sources of records and inclusion criteria of officials. Our principle prioritizes validity over coverage. Based on these datasets, we develop two types of quantitative measures of inter-class and intra-class wage inequality.
Data
Many studies have attempted to estimate official salaries of different dynasties in real terms [55,64–66]. In general, these studies have shown that the Tang dynasty had the highest official salaries, whereas the Ming and Qing dynasties had lower official salaries [56,57].
However, discrepancies do exist due to heterogeneous data sources of records and inclusion criteria of officials. For example, Wang claims that the Han dynasty offered relatively low official salaries based on some secondary data of grassroots officials [66]. In contrast, Zhang studies mid-to-high-ranking officials in the early Han dynasty and claims that Han officials had relatively high salaries compared to other dynasties [67]. Wang includes grassroots officials in the calculation of official wages and observes significant gaps in salaries between different levels of officials [66]. Zhu estimates salaries of officials at all levels in the Jin and Southern & Northern dynasties based on folk stories and poems [53]. His results are inconsistent with Jing who extracts data from more reliable historical archives [68]. Studies using observations at different time points of the Song dynasty do not reach a consensus on the true level of salaries. Gong shows that official salaries in the Song dynasty were among the highest in the Chinese history [65], whereas Mu argues that the average official salaries in the Song dynasty was only one fifth of that in the Tang dynasty [69]. Zhang divides the Song dynasty into four periods and observes an increasing trend of salaries [57]. It is found that in most periods of the Song dynasty officials received at least as high salaries as those in the Tang dynasty. Studies on the Ming and Qing dynasties have fewer inconsistencies. Nevertheless, Hu finds that the average salary of the Ming dynasty is 11.75 times higher than that of ordinary people, which was not low compared to other dynasties [63]. Wang also notices the existence of a significant amount of unreported income and argues that the actual income of Ming officials might be underestimated [62].
To address this debate, we must ensure validity and comparability of data sources. For validity, we only use historical records and documents kept by central governments and exclude literary works, a single specific story, and local records. For comparability, we restrict the sample from the Han dynasty to the Qing dynasty (202 BCE-1912 CE). During the 2,113 years, the hierarchical structure of government system in ancient China had been relatively stable, which determined the authority, responsibilities, and incomes of each rank of officials. Before the Han dynasty, the Shi class followed a very different wage system. For instance, during the early Zhou dynasty (1046–475 BCE), most officials held a noble title, so their income was mainly from rents of their inherited lands. In the late Zhou dynasty (475–221 BCE), the official system transited from the hereditary system to professional bureaucracy, but there were many states with myriads of co-existing salary systems. Although the Qin dynasty (221–206 BCE) was the first empire with a unified official ranking system, it only lasted 15 years. There were no historical records available for analysis. Thus, our sample starts with the Han dynasty, from when the rankings systems were generally comparable, and more data became available. The ending year 1912 marks the fall of imperial China and the beginning of the republic era (see Fig 1 for the timeline).
In terms of the subjects covered in this study, we exclude the emperor’s income/wage due to the lack of available data. As the wealthiest individual in the empire, their exclusion makes our estimated wage inequality a conservative lower bound for imperial China. We also exclude aristocrats without official ranks, as most aristocrats were high-ranking officials and are already included in the data. Additionally, women’s income/wage is omitted from the analysis. In a patriarchal society, women held a subservient position to men, and they generally did not have independent revenue if their brothers, husbands, or sons within the household were alive. This gender hierarchy was reinforced by Neo-Confucianism [40]. Following these principles and criteria, we have collected 25 salary tables spanning over 2000 years from reliable historical records, academic articles, and books (listed in Table 1).
Measures
We use equivalent volumes of rice to measure the real wage. As an agricultural society, rice was the primary commodity in imperial China, so it is an ideal commensurable numeraire. Other types of payments, such as silver, copper coins, and paper money, can be subject to price fluctuations, inflations, and silver import [70,71]. However, it is important to note that rice yields would have increased over time due to agricultural advancements, which could potentially affect the measurement of both peasants’ income and officials’ land rent income. To address this, it is essential to clarify that agricultural output was typically distributed between officials and farmers through land rent. As unit land yields increased, both groups would have been affected proportionally since land rent captured a fixed share of the total agricultural output.
The price data are retrieved from the same sources to keep consistency when translating different forms of salary into equivalent volumes of rice. For instance, the main agriculture product, millet, in the Han dynasty could be converted to rice according to the exchange ratio of 10:6, which means the value of 10 dan millet was equivalent to 6 dan of rice [56,65]. Also, the income from official land was calculated as 35 dan per hectare in the Tang and Song dynasties. According to Zhang, the yield of farmland per hectare was 100 dan [57]. Assume that the rental rate r = 50% of production, and one dan grain was equivalent to 0.7 dan rice. The rent of one hectare was thus 100 × 0.5 × 0.7 = 35 dan.
Our calculation also considers that the actual weight of one dan increased over time. It increased 3% from the Han dynasty to the Jin dynasty, doubled from the Jin dynasty to the Sui dynasty, and then further doubled from the Tang dynasty to the Qing dynasty [72,73]. The overall increase was about 400% from the Han dynasty to the Qing dynasty [56]. To be comparable, we convert different units of dan to the Han convention in our results.
To quantify wage inequality, we use two types of measures: wage ratios (as the baseline measure) and Gini coefficients (as a supplementary measure). The wage ratio between officials and peasants measures the inter-class wage inequality, while the wage ratio between high- and low-ranking officials measures the intra-class wage inequality within the Shi class. Zhang adopts these measures to discuss officials’ relative salary in the Han dynasty [67]. He estimates that the three councilors’ wages were about 47 times higher than those of peasants, whereas state governors’ salaries were about 32 times higher. A similar comparison also exists in Tong Dian, which documents that in the Zhou dynasty the income of an emperor, a high-ranking minister, and a low-ranking official were respectively 320 times, 32 times and 8 times higher than that of a peasant. The wage differential between officials and peasants is the historical counterpart to the public sector wage premium, which is only about 10% in modern times [74].
A partial Gini coefficient can be estimated for the official population and for the official-peasant population. It is supposed to describe the income distribution than wage ratios by considering the weights of population with different wages. However, we must point out that we do not have accurate data on population shares of officials and peasants. Shares within officials are better recorded by historical records (Fig 3) but shares of officials in the entire society were not available. So, our Gini coefficients are at best a partial measure of wage inequality for the official-peasant population (the majority of society), rather than for the entire society. Furthermore, the notion of the “average peasant” in our calculation ignores intra-peasant heterogeneities and regional variations pointed out by Pomeranz [75]. It can lead to underestimation of inequality. Thus, the partial Gini coefficient is more a lower bound measure of inequality.
For the proportions of officials at each rank, we follow Bai’s estimates (Fig 3) and assume that the relative proportions (not absolute numbers) of officials at different ranks remained stable [76,77]. Nevertheless, there are no direct datasets available for the proportions of the Shi class in the population, but we know from historical fiscal records that officials with ranks were about 1% of the total population in all dynasties. Therefore, we use 2% as the lower bound of the class to account for the fact that about half of scholars had no ranks such as grassroots officials (“Li”) and professional academics.
Results
Official wage
Fig 4 plots the average wages of officials with ranks and the Shi class (full details in Table 2). We cannot distinguish aristocrat officials from Shi officials, but the population of aristocrats was ignorable compared to that of the entire Shi class. For simplicity, we treat them as one group in calculating the average wage.
The average wage of officials (and the Shi class in general) features an inverted U shape over the two millennia. In the first millennium (Han, Jin, Southern & Northern, Sui, Tang), average official wage kept rising. In the second millennium (Song, Yuan, Ming, and Qing), official wages underwent a secular decline. Officials in the Tang dynasty earned the highest salaries as found by previous literature [53,56,57]. Also, the Tang dynasty implemented a salary reform to clearly define all hidden forms of income such as food and servant stipends. Similar payroll structure was maintained until the end of the Song dynasty. In contrast, officials in later dynasties lost substantial income from farmlands. A significant portion of their income was generated from the rent collected from these farmlands [78]. Paper money was one of the major forms of salary payment in the Yuan, Ming, and Qing dynasties [60]. High inflation significantly reduced the real purchasing power of salaries in the form of paper money.
Along the trends of official wage, two permanent changes occurred. The first was technological progress, which led to an increase in agricultural productivity from the Han dynasty to the Tang dynasty [79]. This change was responsible for the rising trend of official wage in the first millennium. However, productivity became stagnant in later dynasties until the 19th century when China was forced to open to and learn from the western civilization [39]. The second was the secular concentration of power towards the emperor. From the Sui dynasty onwards, the institutionalization of imperial examinations exacerbated intra-class competition and granted the emperor greater bargaining power. The Neo-Confucianism movement from the Song dynasty introduced new social norms that further curtailed the political power of officials [40]. These changes in explicit and implicit rules played a significant role in the declining trend of official wage in the second millennium.
Wage inequality
Following the methods in Section 3.2, the wage ratios are computed and presented in Figs 5 and 6. It is noted that the ratio between official and peasant wages (inter-class wage inequality) resembles the inverted U shape as in the official wage series. We confirm the quadratic relationship using the simple OLS regression, as shown in column (1) of Table 3. As argued earlier, throughout the imperial epoch, peasant wage remained relatively stable at the subsistence level, showing little increase [26,39,80]. Specifically, recent evidence confirms that the real day wage in the Ming and Qing dynasties remained stable [36].
It is worth emphasizing that peasant wage is not the same as peasant output. Benefits of productivity improvements were either reaped by the ruling class of the empire (the emperor, aristocrats, and officials) or cancelled out by population expansion (the “Malthusian checks”). Therefore, the findings of Broadberry et al. on GDP per capita (output) in China do not refute our assumption on wage [81]. The inverted U relationship is demonstrated by the quadratic regression curve in Fig 5. As argued earlier, the initial increase was mainly due to the improvement in agricultural productivity (the technological mechanism), and the later decrease was mainly due to the continued concentration of political power (the political mechanism).
As the evidence for the political mechanism, the ratio between top- and bottom-ranking official wages (intra-class wage inequality) shows a secular declining trend in Fig 6 and column (2) of Table 3. Behind the narrower pay gap within officials were dynamics of emperor-bureaucracy power tensions. Both institutional arrangements and social norms are embodiment of the power tensions. For example, the introduction of imperial exams during the Sui dynasty led to increased mobility among officials, resulting in higher competition in the Shi class and a weakened collective power against the emperor. The rise of Neo-Confucianism as a social ideology during the Song and Ming dynasties reinforced the hierarchical and patriarchal structure of the society. This ideology granted the emperor an elevated and almost divine status.
Compared to wage ratios, Gini coefficients further account for the population shares of different classes of wage. Readers should be warned that the Gini coefficient computed in this section is inaccurate due to the lack of data on population distribution. We can only obtain a “partial” Gini coefficient (only containing peasants and officials) as a robustness check. Even though our Gini (0.27) in the Qing dynasty is close to the Gini (0.24) estimated based on the social table of the Qing dynasty in 1880 [28]. It provides supporting evidence for the reliability of our benchmarks. As shown in Fig 7, the partial Gini coefficient inherits the inverted U trend of wage ratios illustrated in Fig 5. The initial increase suggests that the positive technological effect dominated the negative political effect in the first millennium. The later decrease in the second millennium indicates that the negative political effects were dominant. The technological effect preceded the political effect because it usually takes longer time for political changes as well as associated institutional and social changes. The fitted curve of the official-peasant Gini is shown in Fig 7, which has an inverted U shape trend like Fig 5. The relationship is also confirmed in column (3) of Table 3.
In contrast, the Gini coefficient among high- and low-ranked officials shows a linear declining trend (column (4)) and follows dynastic “inverted u” cycles as in Fig 6. Here we use the lowercase “u” rather than the uppercase “U” to distinguish between short-term cycles from long-term trends. This cyclical pattern is again driven by emperor-bureaucracy power tensions. At the beginning of a new dynasty, the intra-official Gini coefficient was usually low. This is because founding emperors usually implemented a more equal payroll system to consolidate the new empire. One exception was the Qing dynasty. This is because the first emperor of the Qing dynasty (Shun Zhi) was only 5 years old when he ascended to the imperial position. The dynasty only properly ruled the entire China from the second emperor (Kang Xi) in 1661. Therefore, the actual beginning of the dynasty was much later. In the middle of the dynasties, the intra-official Gini coefficient peaked because wage inequality rose as the power hierarchy expanded and systematic corruption emerged. Towards the end of a dynasty, the intra-official Gini coefficient fell again because uprisings, rebellions, and wars reduced the budget for official salaries. This “inverted u” pattern contributed to the cyclical features. To summarize, the wage inequality features an inverted U trend with inverted u cycles, which we term as the “inverted U-u pattern”.
A unified explanation of wage inequality
To understand the inverted U-u pattern, we propose a unified explanation incorporating technological (T), institutional (I), political (P), and social (S) mechanisms—the TIPS framework, inspired by Milanovic (2016). Our framework can be applied to explain both the long-term trend (i.e., the inverted U trend) and short-term cycles (i.e., the inverted u cycles) of wage inequality, as demonstrated in Fig 8.
The TIPS mechanisms of the “inverted U trends”
(T) The initial push originated from the technological progress during the Han dynasty [39,79]. Under the top-down power hierarchy and bottom-up income ladder of imperial China, the gains in productivity were mainly harvested by the upper class. It led to elevated wage inequality in the first millennium, spanning roughly from the Han dynasty to the Tang dynasty.
(I) To alleviate political tensions arising from the increasing wage inequality, imperial exams were introduced during the Sui dynasty [82]. This institutional shift essentially dealt with high wage inequality by promoting social mobility [49]. This reform bolstered the top-down power hierarchy, as officials (and the overall Shi class) were granted greater opportunities to ascend along the income ladder. The consequence was an expansion in the size and authority of bureaucratic officials [43].
(P) The expansion of officials of the empire not only led to political tensions between the emperor and officials, but also between imperial China (especially the Tang dynasty) and other empires. On the one hand, conflicts between the emperor and influential officials led to more frequent internal rebellions (e.g., An Lushan Rebellion in 755). On the other hand, external wars became more common as the empire reached its peak in the Tang dynasty (e.g., the Eastern Turkic-Tang war in 626, the Baekje-Goguryeo-Silla war in 666, and the Arab-Tang battle of Talas in 751). The surge in military expenses coincided with productivity stagnation, resulting in a decline of wage inequality from late-Tang [83].
Besides, political tensions also affected wage inequality in peaceful times. The periods of rising wage inequality often coincided with a politically powerful bureaucracy (e.g., Han, Jin, Southern & Northern). Since imperial exams were introduced in the Sui dynasty, the supply of bureaucrats became streamlined, so officials and backup scholars were no longer scarce. The negotiation power of the entire Shi class relative to emperors was weakened, contributing to the secular decline in wage inequality (e.g., Song, Ming, and Qing).
(S) Eventually, to address the emperor-bureaucracy tension, social norms rooted in Neo-Confucianism were introduced during the Song dynasty [40,84]. It emphasized moral integrity, social hierarchy, and the importance of maintaining social harmony. These values reinforced the idea of meritocratic governance through the “Ke Ju” examination system, which promoted the rise of individuals based on knowledge and virtue rather than inherited wealth or status. Improved social mobility then induced competition among officials, which further strengthened the emperor’s authority over officials in the Ming and Qing dynasties. As a result, official wage and wage inequality underwent a secular decline as the bargaining power of the Shi class diminished.
The TIPS mechanisms of the “inverted u cycles”
The TIPS framework can also be applied to explain inverted u cycles in each dynasty.
(T) New dynasties were usually born out of bottom-up uprisings (e.g., Han, Ming), internal rebellions (e.g., Sui, Tang, Song), or external wars (e.g., Yuan, Qing). Therefore, they started with relatively low population levels and high marginal labor productivity due to the law of diminishing marginal product. The positive productivity shocks temporarily increased output per capita at the beginning of each dynasty. The surplus output was either channeled by peasants to support higher fertility rates (the “Malthusian checks”) or acquired by the upper class to raise wage inequality.
(I) As the empire developed, its institutions expanded, resulting in a greater number of low-ranking and grassroots officials within the bureaucracy. This increasing scale and complexity often gave rise to inefficiencies, favoritism, and instances of bribery, as officials grappled with navigating intricate administrative procedures and securing their positions. As time passed, specific corrupt practices could take root within the system, as corrupt officials imparted their methods to their successors. The normalization of corruption resulted in a heightened wage inequality, particularly among the officials themselves.
(P) Wage inequality among officials typically began at a low level to solidify the foundations of the new empire. However, in the middle of each dynasty, the central authority of the empire might weaken due to territorial expansion (e.g., Yuan) or the proliferation of regional powers (e.g., Han). The weakening central power can create opportunities for local officials to engage in corrupt practices, resulting in a reduction of intra-class wage inequality but an elevation of inter-class wage inequality. At the same time, officials could leverage their political influence to negotiate their own benefits with emperors. Numerous historical records bear witness to this. For instance, during the early Tang dynasty (634), the imperial secretariat implored the emperor to grant rice salaries to local officials [85]. According to the Old Book of Tang, two grand councilors petitioned for a salary increase due to a spike in rice prices in 777 [86]. Similarly, in 787 an official petitioned for a salary raise for all central government officials, highlighting that their salaries significantly lagged those of local officials [85]. Sometimes, emperors also took the initiative to offer salary increases to gain political support from officials. Such adjustments in salaries were manifestations of the power dynamics between emperors and officials. Eventually, the dynasty was either overturned by bottom-up uprisings (e.g., Ming), internal rebellions (e.g., Tang), or external invasions (e.g., Song). Military expenditures in later phases of dynasties decreased output and wage for all classes, resulting in a decline in wage inequality.
(S) As a dynasty lasted over generations, it gave rise to social norms rooted in the legacies of successive rulers. These implicit rules were utilized by the upper class to govern the lower class (e.g., Confucianism’s dominance during the Han dynasty) or by emperors to constrain officials (e.g., Neo-Confucianism’s emergence during the Song dynasty). Classical Confucianism before the Song dynasty primarily focused on personal and social ethics along with an ideological structure for top-down hierarchical governance. As the “Chinese Renaissance”, Neo-Confucianism entrenched the dominant role of Confucianism from the Song to the Qing dynasties. Essentially, the two schools of thought share the same ethical principles such as loyalty and benevolence in the emperor-official, husband-wife, parent-child, and other interpersonal relationships. The new aspects of Neo-Confucianism were the metaphysical and cosmological concepts such as “Qi” (vital energy) to rationalize those ethical principles. These social norms contributed to mitigating the political tensions facing the emperor at the cost of the lower class and the “middle class” (officials). It is worth reiterating that the wage inequality shown in Fig 6 does not include emperors, so a lower Gini coefficient could coexist with higher inequality between the emperor and the remaining population.
Conclusion
This paper attempts to provide some benchmarks of wage inequality in imperial China over two millennia. Based on historical records of salaries and prices, we convert various forms of wage to equivalent rice volumes for officials and peasants. We discover an “inverted U-u” pattern of the wage ratio between officials and peasants, which gradually increased in the first millennium and declined in the second (inverted U trends) with dynastic cycles (inverted u cycles). In contrast, the wage ratio within officials has a secular decline trend.
We propose a unified TIPS theoretical framework to explain these patterns. Changes in both trends and cycles started with technological disruptions (T) which led to higher wage inequality. Then, institutional arrangements (I) adapted to address the consequences of higher inequality but further exacerbated it. As a result, political tensions (P) grew between the upper and lower classes, between the emperor and officials, as well as between imperial China and other empires. Consequently, bottom-up uprisings, internal rebellions, and external wars squeezed the budget for official salaries and reduced wage inequality. Gradually, social norms (S) evolved to reinforce the existing power structure, leading to lower inequality paired with lower mobility, until the empire collapsed from inside or was conquered from outside. The TIPS framework holds for both long-term inverted U trends over the two millennia and short-term inverted u cycles within dynasties.
These factors are still relevant today. For example, the rapid development and deployment of automation and AI in the past few decades (T) have transformed industries such as manufacturing, retail, and services. While these technologies have increased productivity and efficiency, they have disproportionately benefited highly skilled workers in tech and innovation sectors, while displacing lower-skilled workers in more traditional jobs. This has led to a widening wage gap between highly paid professionals and lower-wage workers, increasing overall wage inequality. In response to the growing inequality caused by technological disruption, governments and institutions (I) have implemented various policies, such as tax incentives for tech companies, deregulation of certain industries, and targeted education and reskilling programs. However, these measures have struggled to keep pace with the speed of technological change, leaving many workers behind. As inequality has risen, political tensions (P) have emerged between different socio-economic groups. In many countries, the working class has expressed frustration over stagnant wages and job losses, while elites in the tech and finance sectors have thrived. These tensions have manifested in populist movements, protests, and rising polarization in political discourse. In some cases, these movements have challenged traditional political elites, leading to the election of outsider candidates and shifts in policy priorities. Over time, social norms (S) have adapted to these changes, reinforcing existing power structures. In some societies, the narrative of technological progress has been used to justify growing inequality, with arguments that innovation and efficiency will eventually “trickle down” to benefit all. This has led to greater acceptance of income and wealth disparities, and in some cases, has slowed efforts to reduce inequality through stronger redistributive policies. Nevertheless, this also results in lower social mobility, as access to opportunities becomes increasingly tied to one’s position in the socio-economic hierarchy.
Therefore, current policymakers are suggested to be proactive and keep updated in their interventions to counteract inequality arising from new technologies. Progressive tax policies, redistribution mechanisms, and investments in education and reskilling programs could help ensure that the benefits of technological innovation are more evenly distributed.
One limitation of our method is that we place a higher priority on the validity and comparability of data sources. This approach comes at the expense of excluding numerous unofficial data sources, such as genealogies [48], folk stories, and poems [53], which could provide broader coverage of social classes and sample periods. Nevertheless, our estimates can serve as benchmarks for future studies when new sources of data become available. In addition, we use the wage ratio between officials and peasants to measure inter-class wage inequality. However, it is important to consider that as commerce and industry developed, particularly from the Tang dynasty onwards, the economic structure became more diversified, and the relevance of peasant income as a baseline for measuring overall wage inequality may have shifted. The growth of urban centers and the expansion of trade and industrial activities created new sources of wealth and income beyond agriculture. As a result, merchants, artisans, and industrial workers increasingly contributed to the economy, potentially altering the dynamics of income distribution. A more comprehensive measure of wage inequality would need to consider the emerging wage disparities within commerce and industry, as well as the interactions between these sectors and traditional agriculture.
Supporting information
S1 File. Data and code can be found in the zip file of the supporting information.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0315627.s001
(ZIP)
References
- 1. Kuznets Simon (1955) “Economic Growth and Economic Inequality,” American Economic Review (45): 1–28.
- 2. Van Zanden J. L. (1995). Tracing the Beginning of the Kuznets Curve: Western Europe during the Early Modern Period. The Economic History Review, 48(4), 643–664.
- 3. Barro R. J. (2000). Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries. Journal of Economic Growth, 5(1), 5–32.
- 4. Banerjee A. V., & Duflo E. (2003). Inequality and Growth: What Can the Data Say? Journal of Economic Growth, 8(3), 267–299.
- 5.
Lindert Peter H. (1991). Toward a comparative history of income and wealth inequality. In Income distribution in historical perspective, edited by Brenner Y.S., Kaelble H. and Thomas M., 212–231. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
- 6.
Lindert Peter H. 2000. Three centuries of inequality in Britain and America. In Handbook of Income Distribution, edited by Atkinson A.B. and Bourguignon F., 167–216. London: Elsevier.
- 7. Piketty Thomas (2003) “Income Inequality in France, 1901–1998,” Journal of Political Economy (111): 1004–1042.
- 8. Alfani G. (2021). Economic Inequality in Preindustrial Times: Europe and Beyond. Journal of Economic Literature, 59(1), 3–44.
- 9. Milanovic B. (2016). Global Inequality: a new approach for the age of globalization. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.
- 10. Wisman J. D. (2017). Politics, Not Economics, Ultimately Drives Inequality. Challenge, 60(4), 347–367.
- 11. Acemoglu Daron, and Autor David H. (2011) “Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Implications for Employment and Earnings,” in David Card and Orley (ed.) Handbook of Labor Economics. Vol. 4B. North Holland: 1043–1171.
- 12. Aghion Philippe, Akcigit Ufuk, Bergeaud Antonin, Blundell Richard, and Hemous David (2015) “Innovation and Top Income Inequality.” Working paper, Nation Bureau of Economic Research.
- 13. Erman L., & te Kaat D. M. (2019). Inequality and growth: industry-level evidence. Journal of Economic Growth, 24(3), 283–308.
- 14. Philippon Thomas, and Reshef Ariell (2012) “Wages and Human Capital in the U.S. Financial Industry: 1909–2006,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics (127): 1551–1609.
- 15. Bell Brain, and John Van Reenen (2010) “Bankers’ Pay and Extreme Wage Inequality in the UK.” Working paper, London School of Economics.
- 16. Kaplan Steven, N., and Joshua Rauh (2010) “Wall Street and Main Street: What Contributes to the Rise in the Highest Incomes?” Review of Financial Studies (23): 1004–1050.
- 17. Benabou Roland, and Jean Tirole (2016) “Bonus Culture: Competitive Pay, Screening, and Multitasking.” Journal of Political Economy (124): 305–370.
- 18. Gordon Robert, J., and Ian Dew-Becker (2008) “Controversies about the Rise of American Inequality: A Survey,” Working paper. National Bureau of Economic Research.
- 19. Alfani G., & Ryckbosch W. (2016). Growing apart in early modern Europe? A comparison of inequality trends in Italy and the Low Countries, 1500–1800. Explorations in Economic History, 62, 143–153.
- 20. Haskel Jonathan, Lawrence Robert Z., Leamer Edward E., and Slaughter Matthew J. (2012) “Globalization and U.S. Wages: Modifying Classic Theory to Explain Recent Facts,” Journal of Economic Perspectives (26): 119–140.
- 21.
Atkinson Anthony, B., and Thomas Piketty (2010) Top Incomes over the Twentieth Century ‐ A Global Perspective. Vol. 2. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
- 22. Piketty Thomas, and Saez Emmanuel (2003) “Income Inequality in the United States, 1913–1998,” Quarterly Journal of Economics (118): 1–39.
- 23. Piketty Thomas, and Saez Emmanuel (2014) “Inequality in the long run,” Science (344): 838–843.
- 24. Rothschild Casey, and Scheuer Florian (2016) “Optimal Taxation with Rent-Seeking,” The Review of Economic Studies (83): 1225–1262.
- 25. Chu A. C., & Peretto P. F. (2023). Innovation and inequality from stagnation to growth. European Economic Review, 160, 104615.
- 26. Galor O., & Moav O. (2002). Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1133–1191.
- 27. Galor O., & Weil D. N. (2000). Population, technology, and growth: From Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review, 90(4), 806–828.
- 28. Milanovic B., Lindert P. H., & Williamson J. G. (2011). Pre-Industrial Inequality. The Economic Journal, 121(551), 255–272.
- 29. Bengtsson E., & Waldenström D. (2018). Capital Shares and Income Inequality: Evidence from the Long Run. The Journal of Economic History, 78(3), 712–743.
- 30. Alfani G., Gierok V., & Schaff F. (2022). Economic Inequality in Preindustrial Germany, ca. 1300–1850. The Journal of Economic History, 82(1), 87–125.
- 31. Montalbo A. (2023). Landholding Inequality and the Consolidation of Democracy: Evidence from Nineteenth-Century France. The Journal of Economic History, 83(1), 203–241.
- 32. Lindert P., & Nafziger S. (2014). Russian Inequality on the Eve of Revolution. The Journal of Economic History, 74(3), 767–798.
- 33. Williamson J. (1980). Earnings Inequality in Nineteenth-Century Britain. The Journal of Economic History, 40(3), 457–475.
- 34. Stelzner M. (2015). Income Inequality in the United States in the Late 1860s. The Journal of Economic History, 75(3), 889–900.
- 35. Allen R. C., Bassino J. P., Ma D., Moll-Murata C., & Van Zanden J. L. (2011). Wages, prices, and living standards in China, 1738–1925: in comparison with Europe, Japan, and India. The Economic History Review, 64(s1), 8–38.
- 36. Liu Z. (2024). Wages, labour markets, and living standards in China, 1530–1840. Explorations in Economic History, 92, 101569.
- 37. Leese-Messing K. (2022). Tools of Economic Activity in Early Imperial China. In S. von Reden (Ed.), Handbook of Ancient Afro-Eurasian Economies Volume 2: Local, Regional, and Imperial Economies (Vol. 2, pp. 531–588). Berlin/Boston: Walter de Gruyter.
- 38. Kracke E. (1952). The Early Economic History of China. The Journal of Economic History, 12(2), 160–163.
- 39. Yang Gui (1991) “The Agriculture Labor Productivity in Ancient Guanzhong Region,” [Chinese] Agricultural History of China (3): 10–15.
- 40. Dong B., & Zhang Y. (2023). Confucianism and science. Explorations in Economic History, 101517.
- 41. Scheidel W. (2009). Rome and China: comparative perspectives on ancient world empires: Oxford University Press.
- 42. Terpstra T. (2020). Roman technological progress in comparative context: The Roman Empire, Medieval Europe and Imperial China. Explorations in Economic History, 75, 101300.
- 43. Von Glahn R. (2016). The Economic History of China: Cambridge University Press.
- 44.
Chen, Xiaodong; Mi, Haoming; Zhou, Peng. 2024. Whether to decentralize and how to decentralize? The optimal fiscal federalism in an endogenous growth model. Applied Economics, 56(29): 3499–3516.
- 45. Mitchell A. M., & Yin W. (2022). Political centralization, career incentives, and local economic growth in Edo Japan. Explorations in Economic History, 85, 101446.
- 46. Scheidel W. (2014). State power in ancient China and Rome: Oxford University Press.
- 47.
Loewe Michael (1968) Everyday Life in Early Imperial China During the Han Period 202 BC–AD 220. London: Hackett Publishing.
- 48. Shiue C. H. (2017). Human capital and fertility in Chinese clans before modern growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 22(4), 351–396.
- 49. Yang Xiaoliang; Zhou Peng. 2022. Wealth inequality and social mobility: A simulation-based modelling approach. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 196: 307–329.
- 50. Ni S., & Van P. H. (2006). High corruption income in Ming and Qing China. Journal of Development Economics, 81(2), 316–336.
- 51. Sng T.-H. (2014). Size and dynastic decline: The principal-agent problem in late imperial China, 1700–1850. Explorations in Economic History, 54, 107–127.
- 52.
Huang Huixian, and Chen Feng (2012) History of Chinese Salary System. Wuhan, PRC: Wuhan University Press.
- 53. Zhu Dawei (1986) The Official Salary System in the Wei, Jin, and Southern and Northern Dynasties, Research In Chinese Economic History (4): 61–72.
- 54.
Lin Xinqi (2004) Chinese Personnel Management History. Beijing, PRC: China Social Sciences Press.
- 55. Liu Haifeng (1985) “On the Changes in the Material and Monetary Payment to Officials in the Tang Dynasty,” [Chinese] The Journal of Chinese Social and Economic History (2): 18–29.
- 56. Huang Miantang (2002) “A Comprehensive Survey of Grain Prices in Chinese History,” [Chinese] Journal of Literature, History and Philosophy (2): 33–48.
- 57. Zhang Quanming (1997) On the Official Salary in the Song Dynasty, [Chinese] Historical Research (2): 135–149.
- 58.
Qi Xia (1999) China’s Economic History (Volume of the Song Dynasty). Beijing, PRC: China Economic Daily Press.
- 59.
Cheng Minsheng (2008) A Study of the Commodity Price in the Song Dynasty. Beijing, PRC: People’s Publishing House.
- 60. Naonori Maeda, and Yao Shuomin (1985) “The Change in Value of Paper Money in the Yuan Dynasty,” [Chinese] China Numismatics (4): 46–53.
- 61. Liu Wenrui (1986) “Officials Salaries in Ancient China,” [Chinese] Relics and Museology (3): 79–87.
- 62. Wang Yinghua (2000) “The Official Salary System in the Ming Dynasty.” [Chinese] Collected Papers of History Studies (2): 82–89.
- 63. Hu Tieqiu (2012) “The Change in the Official Salary System and the Introduction of Single Whip Law in the Ming dynasty.” [Chinese] Journal of Historical Science (11): 22–42.
- 64. Ju Fangan (2001) “Changes on Salaries of Civil Officials in the Late Qing Dynasty Civil Service System Reform,” [Chinese] Journal of Renmin University of China (5): 118–124.
- 65. Gong Yanming (1991) “The Official Management System of Song Dynasty,” [Chinese] Historical Research (6): 45–61.
- 66. Wang Jun (2003) “Reflections upon Studies on the Salary System in Chinese History,” [Chinese] Review of Economic Research (83): 2–12.
- 67. Zhang Zhaokai (1996) On the Salary System of the Han Dynasty, [Chinese] Chinese Social and Economic History (1): 1–8.
- 68. Jing Youquan (1988) “Several Questions About the Salary System of the Northern Wei dynasty.” [Chinese] Journal of Northeast Normal University (5): 43–45.
- 69. Mu Zhaoqing (1992) “On the System of Farmland-Type Payment to Officials in the Song Dynasty: an Evaluation of the Policy that ‘Nourishes the Honesty with High Salaries’,” [Chinese] The Academic Journal of Zhongzhou (4): 132–137.
- 70. Broadberry S. & Gupta B. (2006) The early modern great divergence: wages, prices and economic development in Europe and Asia, 1500–1800. The Economic History Review, 59: 2–31.
- 71. Kobayashi A. (2022). Asia’s Silver Absorption through the Triangular Settlement System, 1846–1870. The Journal of Economic History, 82(2), 442–479.
- 72. Liang Fangzhong (1980) “The Change of Weights and Measures and Era Characteristic of Chinese Dynasties,” [Chinese] Journal of Sun Yat-sen University (Social Sciences) (2): 1–20.
- 73. Wu Hui (1992) “The Weights and Measures on the Dynasties of Wei, Jin, Southern and Northern, Sui, and Tang,” [Chinese] The Journal of Chinese Social and Economic History (3): 7–18.
- 74.
Minford, Patrick; Wang, Yi; Zhou, Peng. 2020. Resolving the Public-Sector Wage Premium Puzzle by Indirect Inference. Applied Economics, 52(7): 726–741.
- 75. Pomeranz K. (2000). The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy: Princeton University Press.
- 76. Bai Gang (2007) The History of Chinese Political System. Shanghai, PRC: Social Science Academic Press.
- 77. Zhu Ruixi (1996) Book Song. Bai Gang (ed.) History of Chinese Political System. Beijing, PRC: People’s Publishing House.
- 78. Cao Wenzhu (1986) “The Official Salary System of the Southern Dynasty in Eastern Jin.” [Chinese] Journal of Beijing Normal University (Social Sciences) (1): 67–74.
- 79. Hu Ji (1983) “One Gain out of Three Times of Farming: the Problem in the Production Efficiency and Production Structure of Traditionally Small-Scale Peasant Economy in China,” [Chinese] Agricultural History of China (4): 23–33.
- 80. Maddison A. (1998). Chinese Economic Performance in the Long Run. OECD Publishing.
- 81. Broadberry S., Guan H., & Li D. D. (2018). China, Europe, and the Great Divergence: A Study in Historical National Accounting, 980–1850. The Journal of Economic History, 78(4), 955–1000.
- 82. Kracke Edward, A. Jr. (1967). “Region, Family, and Individual in the Chinese Examination System,” in John K. Fairbank (ed.) Chinese Thoughts and Institutions. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
- 83.
Li Fang (2011) Imperial Readings of the Taiping Era. Beijing, PRC: Zhonghua Book Company.
- 84. Wilson Thomas., A. (1996) “The Ritual Formation of Confucian Orthodoxy and the Descendants of the Sage,” The Journal of Asian Studies (55):559–584.
- 85.
Wang, Pu(1955) Tang Hui Yao. Beijing, PRC: Zhonghua Book Company.
- 86.
Liu, Xu (1936) The Old Book of Tang. Shanghai, PRC: Commercial Press.