Skip to main content
Advertisement
Browse Subject Areas
?

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here.

  • Loading metrics

Mean Field Approximation for Biased Diffusion on Japanese Inter-Firm Trading Network

Abstract

By analysing the financial data of firms across Japan, a nonlinear power law with an exponent of 1.3 was observed between the number of business partners (i.e. the degree of the inter-firm trading network) and sales. In a previous study using numerical simulations, we found that this scaling can be explained by both the money-transport model, where a firm (i.e. customer) distributes money to its out-edges (suppliers) in proportion to the in-degree of destinations, and by the correlations among the Japanese inter-firm trading network. However, in this previous study, we could not specifically identify what types of structure properties (or correlations) of the network determine the 1.3 exponent. In the present study, we more clearly elucidate the relationship between this nonlinear scaling and the network structure by applying mean-field approximation of the diffusion in a complex network to this money-transport model. Using theoretical analysis, we obtained the mean-field solution of the model and found that, in the case of the Japanese firms, the scaling exponent of 1.3 can be determined from the power law of the average degree of the nearest neighbours of the network with an exponent of −0.7.

Introduction

Complex networks have been extensively studied over the last decade [1][3]. Problems of transport on complex networks, which are some of the most fundamental problems concerning the physics of complex networks, have also been intensively studied. For example, random walks on complex networks have been investigated from various viewpoints [4][6]. One application of transport on complex networks is PageRank, which corresponds to the steady-state density of transport caused by random walks on the Internet. PageRank is one of the most successful indices evaluating the importance of web pages and has been utilized by internet search engines.

Most studies regarding transport on complex networks have been based on theoretical approaches; however, recently the problems of actual transport on complex networks have also been studied by using massive data analysis. Examples of such problems include, airport traffic on the worldwide airport network [7], the number of trains on the Indian railway network [8], the flow of viewers on portal sites [9] and control flows on stock-ownership networks [10][12].

In a previous study, we analysed the empirical data from an inter-firm trading network, which consisted of approximately one million Japanese firms, and the sales of these firms (a sale corresponds to the total in-flow into a node) to investigate the actual transport phenomenon in a complex network [13]. This inter-firm trading network is known to be a typical complex network with a power law degree distribution [13], [14], a negative degree-degree correlation [13], [15], a small world property [14], community structures [16], power laws of money flows [15], [17] and an asymmetric behaviour of authorities and hubs explained by a network-evolution model based on the preferential attachment rule [18], [19]. To be more precise, we obtained the following results from Ref. [13]: (i) we found a non-trivial empirical power law with an exponent of 1.3 between the number of business partners in a firm and its sales by analysing the data; (ii) we introduced a simple money-transport model in which a firm (i.e. a customer) distributes money to its out-edges (i.e. suppliers) in proportion to the in-degree of the destinations; (iii) using numerical simulations, we found that the steady flow of the abovementioned inter-firm trading network derived from this model can approximately reproduce a power-law scaling with an exponent of 1.3 between the number of business partners (i.e. degrees of the network) and sales. Furthermore, the sales distribution of the actual firms obeys the power law distribution with an exponent of approximately 1. Moreover, the sales of individual firms derived from the money-transport model are shown to be proportional to the real sales on the average. However, we also showed that the simple random walk model (i.e., PageRank) in which a firm is assumed to evenly distribute to all its outgoing neighbours does not reproduce the empirical scaling with an exponent of 1.3. This result implies that PageRank does not correspond to the sales. Note that scaling with an exponent of 1.3 was observed are observed by analysing the abovementioned Japanese financial data not only between the sales and degrees but also between other important firm-size indicators, for instance, between sales and number of employees, between profits and number of employees, between profits and degrees, etc. [20].

In the previous study [13], we could not specifically identify what types of structure properties (or correlations) of the Japanese inter-firm trading network determine the 1.3 exponent, although we found that we need a particular network structure to be reproduced in our framework using numerical simulations. Therefore, the current study is devoted to the theoretical study of the results of Ref. [13]. In particular, we apply a mean-field approximation to the models to clarify how the exponents of the power-law relationships, specifically between the degree of the inter-firm trading network (i.e. the number of business partners) and sales depend on the network structure.

In this paper, we start in Section 2 by reviewing the models and the numerical results of the previous study. Next, we introduce the mean-field approximation for these models and reveal the relationships between the power-law exponent, models, and networks in Section 3. Finally, we summarize and present our conclusions in Section 4.

Power Laws for Diffusion on Inter-Firm Trading Network

In this section, we review the results of Ref. [13]. To understand the empirical scaling with exponent 1.3 between degrees and sales, we introduced the following money-transport models [13].

Model-1 (Equi-partition model):(1)

Model-2 (Weighted partition model):(2)where denotes the sales of node at time step , is an adjacency matrix, is the in-degree of node , is the out-degree of node and is the number of nodes on the network. Note that for in Eq. (1) or in Eq. (2), we omit the contributions of the node .

In Model-1, a node representing a business firm is assumed to evenly distribute its total in-flow (i.e. sales) at time t to all its outgoing neighbours in the next time step. This transport is equivalent to the simple probability diffusion of the PageRank model in the case of no random spontaneous jumping [4]. However, for Model-2, a node distributes its sales to its outgoing neighbours in proportion to the destinations’ in-degrees. This model is one of the so-called biased random walk models [21].

We used two types of networks for numerical experiments to clarify the dependencies on the firm network [13]. The data set used in the generation of networks and the data analysis in Refs. [13], [20] was provided by Tokyo Shoko Research, Ltd. and contains approximately one million firms, which practically covers all active firms in Japan. For each firm, the data set contains the annual sales and a list of business partners in 2005, categorized into suppliers and customers [13], [14], [20].

The first network is the real firm network whose nodes are firms and whose edges are defined by the following rule: if firm purchases goods and/or services from firm , or, equivalently, if money flows from firm to firm , we connect node to node with a directed link (there are 961,318 nodes and 3,783,711 edges) [13], [14]. This network was generated by using the business partners data in the abovementioned data set. The firm network is a typical complex network whose main properties are as follows: (i)a power-law degree distribution with exponent 1.3, (ii)a negative degree-degree correlation and (iii)a small-world property (the mean distance between nodes is 5.62 and the maximum distance is 21) [13], [14], [16].

The second network is the shuffled firm network, which is an almost-uncorrelated network with the same degree distribution as the firm network generated by the Maslov-Sneppen algorithm [22], [23]. Note that we simulated the time evolution of the models on the largest strongly connected component (LSCC) for each network to neglect boundary effects. Then, total money is conserved, on the LSCCs of both networks.

For all combinations of models and networks, we obtained by numerical simulations the following power law for large () [13]:(3)

Here, is the conditional mean of for a given as a function of and is defined by(4)where is the separator of box , taken evenly in logarithmic space, e.g. , and on the right-hand side is represented by the geometric mean . The exponent depends on both the network and model. These dependencies are summarized in Table 1. Note that Model 2 for the firm network reproduces the empirical scaling with exponent 1.3.

Mean-Field Approximation for Models

In this section, we apply the mean-field approximation to the models to understand the relationship between the exponents, models, and network structures as shown in Table 1. Here we neglect the directions of the networks for simplicity (scalings nearly identical to results presented in the previous section can be obtained by numerical simulation, regardless of whether or not the edge directions are neglected). By assuming , we can regard the models as Markov processes with an existing probability of ,(5)where is the transition probability from node to node [13]. Note that although we neglect the direction of edges in this paper, the following discussion can be extended to the case of a directed network by adding some assumptions and calculations.

In general, one of the mean-field solutions of the Markov process defined by the transition matrix(6)is given in Ref. [24] by(7)where is the weight of the transition probability to a node with the degree , which is defined as a function of the degree , is the probability that the walker is at any node of degree in the steady state, is a probability density function of degree and is the conditional probability that a node of degree is connected to a node of degree . To obtain this solution, the authors of Ref. [24] employed mainly two approximations. First, they used the annealed network approximation where they regarded the sets of firms with common degrees in the original network as nodes of the approximated network, and the weighted edges of the approximated network are associated with a probability that two nodes of degrees and are connected,(8)where is denoted as a sum over the set of nodes of degree [24]. Second, they replaced with average probability of an interaction between nodes of degree and , defined by

(9)Then, we can replaced the Markov process given by Eq. 5 with(10)where is the probability that the walker is at any node of degree at time . By substituting Eq. 7 into this equation and by using the degree detailed balance condition, , we confirm that Eq. 7 is a steady state of Eq. 10. More details on these approximations are available in Ref. [24]

Next, we apply Eq. 7 to our models given by Eqs. 1 and 2. In Model-1, the transition probability is uniform; that is, in Eq. 6. Therefore, the conditional mean of sales for the given degree (i.e. per node), is written as(11)

This scaling agrees with simulation results for Model-1 for the firm network and the shuffled network.

Similarly, by applying Eq. 7 to the case that in Eq. 6 (corresponding to Model-2), we obtain(12)where we denote the average degree of nearest neighbours as [25]. Thus, we find

(13)From Fig. 1(a) in Ref. [13], we see that for a large degree in the case of the firm network. We substitute this empirical result into Eq. 13 to obtain(14)

thumbnail
Figure 1. The cumulative distribution function of degree of the artificial networks.

We confirm that degree obeys the power law distribution with exponent −1.3, namely, .

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0091704.g001

This scaling corresponds to the simulation results for Model-2 for the firm network and empirical observation. Note that Eq. 13 implies that the exponents depend on the average degree of nearest neighbourhoods, for Model-2.

For the shuffled network for Model-2, which is the uncorrelated network shown in Fig. 1(a) of Ref. [13] (i.e. ), we obtain the following from Eq. 13:(15)

This equation agrees with the numerical result.

Finally, we numerically check the approximation by using different artificial networks that have power-law degree distributions with exponent 1.3 and power-law average degrees of nearest neighbours like the firm network. The artificial networks satisfy the following conditions:

  • The degree obeys the power law distribution, .
  • The average degree of the nearest neighbours is expressed as a power function of the degree, .

To generate networks that satisfy the above conditions, we modify the configuration model as follows:

  1. Assign the degree sequence, , obeying the power law with exponent to nodes . For example, (), where is the number of nodes and is the largest integer not greater than .
  2. Randomly sample a node denoted by the from the set of nodes that have the largest .
  3. Update ; .
  4. Randomly sample a node denoted by from all nodes except for node with probability proportional to , where .
  5. Update ; .
  6. Connect node and with an edge (undirected).
  7. Repeat steps 2 through 6 until ().

Figures 1 and 2 show the cumulative distribution the function of degree, which corresponds to and the average degree of nearest neighbours as a function of degree for the artificial network with parameter (empirical parameter), (empirical parameter), and . In addition, Figures 3 and 4 show the mean of the sales as a function of degree , which is numerically derived from Eqs. 1 and 2 for the corresponding artificial networks. From these figures, we can confirm that all scaling exponents obtained numerically accord with the results of the approximations given by Eq. 11 for Model-1 and by Eq. 13 for Model-2. Moreover, from Figure 4, we confirm that only the case , which is the empirical observation of for the firm network, reproduces the empirical scaling 1.3.

thumbnail
Figure 2. The averages degree of nearest neighbours as a function of degree of the artificial networks, .

The black triangles indicate the network for , the red nablas for and the green squares for . The black dashed line is proportional to , the red dash-dotted line is proportional to and the green dash-double-dotted line is proportional to .

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0091704.g002

thumbnail
Figure 3. The mean of sales as a function of degree, , for Model-1.

We plot the scaled values []. The black triangles indicate the network for , the red nablas for and the green squares for . The mean of sales as a function of degree, , for Model-1. From this figure, we can confirm that is proportional to regardless of . These results agree with the approximation given by Eq. 11, namely, .

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0091704.g003

thumbnail
Figure 4. The mean of sales as a function of degree, , for Model-2.

We plot the scaled values []. The black triangles indicate the network for , the red nablas for , the green squares for , the black dashed line is proportional to , the red dash-dotted line is proportional to and the green dash-double-dotted line is proportional to . These results agree with the approximation given by Eq. 13; namely, . The result for [i.e. ] corresponds to empirical scaling with exponent 1.3.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0091704.g004

Conclusion and Discussion

In this study, by applying the mean-field approximation to the money-transport models given by Eqs. 1 and 2, we were able to consistently understand the relationships, between the power-law exponents, models and network structures summarised in Table 1. In particular, we presented the connections of the non-trivial power law scaling with an exponent of 1.3 (in Model-2 for the firm network) with the average degree of the nearest neighbours , which is one of the cardinal features of a network. This result is one of the explanations for empirical scaling relationships with exponent 1.3 between the number of business partners and sales. Moreover, non-trivial empirical scaling with exponent 1.3 between sales and number of employees , , which is observed in Ref. [20], might be connected to the network structure. Because, roughly speaking, combining the scaling between sales and degrees , , described in this study, and the trivial empirical scaling between number of employees and degrees , reported in Ref. [20], we obtain the scaling between employees and sales, .

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank Enago (www.enago.jp) for the English language review.

Author Contributions

Conceived and designed the experiments: HW. Performed the experiments: HW. Analyzed the data: HW. Contributed reagents/materials/analysis tools: HW. Wrote the paper: HW.

References

  1. 1. Newman M (2003) The structure and function of complex networks. SIAM review 45: 167–256.
  2. 2. Boccaletti S, Latora V, Moreno Y, Chavez M, Hwang D (2006) Complex networks: Structure and dynamics. Phys Rep 424: 175–308.
  3. 3. Albert R, Barabási A (2002) Statistical mechanics of complex networks. Reviews of modern physics 74: 47.
  4. 4. Brin S, Page L (1998) The anatomy of a large-scale hypertextual web search engine. Computer networks and ISDN systems 30: 107–117.
  5. 5. Noh J, Rieger H (2004) Random walks on complex networks. Phys Rev Lett 92: 118701.
  6. 6. Litvak N, Scheinhardt W, Volkovich Y, Zwart B (2009) Characterization of tail dependence for in-degree and pagerank. Algorithms and Models for the Web-Graph : 90–103.
  7. 7. Guimera R, Mossa S, Turtschi A, Amaral L (2005) The worldwide air transportation network: Anomalous centrality, community structure, and cities’ global roles. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 102: 7794–7799.
  8. 8. Sen P, Dasgupta S, Chatterjee A, Sreeram P, Mukherjee G, et al. (2003) Small-world properties of the indian railway network. Phys Rev E 67: 036106.
  9. 9. Chmiel A, Kowalska K, Hołyst JA (2009) Scaling of human behavior during portal browsing. Phys Rev E 80: 066122.
  10. 10. Glattfelder J, Battiston S (2009) Backbone of complex networks of corporations: The ow of control. Phys Rev E 80: 036104.
  11. 11. Vitali S, Glattfelder J, Battiston S (2011) The network of global corporate control. PloS one 6: e25995.
  12. 12. Vitali S, Battiston S (2011) Geography versus topology in the european ownership network. New J Phys 13: 063021.
  13. 13. Watanabe H, Takayasu H, Takayasu M (2012) Biased diffusion on the japanese inter-firm trading network: estimation of sales from the network structure. New J Phys 14: 043034.
  14. 14. Ohnishi T, Takayasu H, Takayasu M (2009) Hubs and authorities on Japanese inter-firm network: Characterization of nodes in very large directed networks. Prog Theor Phys 179: 157–166.
  15. 15. Tamura K, Miura W, Takayasu M, Takayasu H, Kitajima S, et al.. (2012) Estimation of ux be-tween interacting nodes on huge inter-firm networks. In: International Journal of Modern Physics: Conference Series. World Scientific, volume 16, 93–104.
  16. 16. Iino T, Kamehama K, Iyetomi H, Ikeda Y, Ohnishi T, et al.. (2010) Community structure in a large-scale transaction network and visualization. In: Journal of Physics: Conference Series. IOP Publishing, volume 221, p. 012012.
  17. 17. Tamura K, Miura W, Takayasu M, Takayasu H, Kitajima S, et al.. (2012) Money-transport on a japanese inter-firm networks: Estimating sales from the adjacency matrix. In: Proceedings of The Asia Pacific Symposium on Intelligent and Evolutionary Systems Kyoto Japan (ISBN978-4-99066920-1).
  18. 18. Miura W, Takayasu H, Takayasu M (2012) Effect of coagulation of nodes in an evolving complex network. Phys Rev Lett 108: 168701.
  19. 19. Miura W, Takayasu H, Takayasu M (2012) The origin of asymmetric behavior of money ow in the business firm network. The European Physical Journal Special Topics 212: 65–75.
  20. 20. Watanabe H, Takayasu H, Takayasu M (2013) Relations between allometric scalings and uctuations in complex systems: The case of Japanese firms. Physica A 392: 741–756.
  21. 21. Fronczak A, Fronczak P (2009) Biased random walks in complex networks: The role of local navigation rules. Phys Rev E 80: 016107.
  22. 22. Milo R, Kashtan N, Itzkovitz S, Newman M, Alon U (2003) On the uniform generation of random graphs with prescribed degree sequences. arXiv preprint cond-mat/0312028.
  23. 23. Maslov S, Sneppen K (2002) Specificity and stability in topology of protein networks. Science Signalling 296: 910.
  24. 24. Baronchelli A, Pastor-Satorras R (2010) Mean-field diffusive dynamics on weighted networks. Phys Rev E 82: 011111.
  25. 25. Costa L, Rodrigues F, Travieso G, Boas P (2007) Characterization of complex networks: A survey of measurements. Adv Phys 56: 167–242.