Skip to main content
Advertisement
Browse Subject Areas
?

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here.

  • Loading metrics

Capital Growth Paths of the Neoclassical Growth Model

Abstract

This paper derives the first-order approximated paths of both types of capital in the two-capital neoclassical growth model. The derived capital growth paths reveal that the short-run growth effect of capital injection differs considerably depending on which type of capital is enhanced. This result demonstrates the importance of well-targeted capital enhancement programs such as public sector projects and foreign aid.

Introduction

For the last half century, the neoclassical model of economic growth [1] has been the most widely used starting point for analyses of long-term economic growth. Since its conception as a model with a single output produced from two inputs, capital and labour, it has been extended to cover a wide range of topics. Human capital development [2], international trade [3], technological spillover [4], cross-country differences in endowment [5], and exploitation of exhaustible resources [6] are some examples. The model has also evolved methodologically by being covered to a stochastic model [7], merged into the general equilibrium framework [8], linked to the Euler equation [9], and hybridised with the endogenous growth model [10].

These developments notwithstanding, the core of the neoclassical growth model remains its original setting. Not only is it simple and clear in concept, it is empirically testable [11], owing to the well-known reduced form equation to measure the so-called conditional convergence.

Yet despite its popularity, there has been little consensus in the literature whether the Solow model is indeed a good representation of the real economy. Some economists from the endogenous growth school believe that there is no reason to expect convergence even in the long run; and even amongst the neoclassical economists the possibility of the Malthusian trap attributable to the economy's initial condition has been raised as both a theoretical and an empirical issue [12], [13]. There is also a suggestion that the widespread test of convergence is, in fact, not a genuine test of convergence but rather a joint test of convergence and of other model specifications, given that the test result is dependent on the model's assumption regarding the technological growth [14].

Perhaps the single largest cause of this disagreement is biasedness of estimators from the convergence regression. Various types of bias has been reported in the literature: sources of upwards bias include finite sample size [15], within-group estimation [16] and the closed economy assumption commonly employed in cross-sectional analyses [17], while sources of downwards bias include omitted fixed effects [18] and inclusion of human capital into the model when in reality such capital does not significantly contribute to growth [11]. This rich collection of upwards and downwards forces makes accurate measurement of the speed of convergence challenging, with most parameters being either overestimated or underestimated. While development of empirical methodology such as use of panel data can correct the bias to a certain extent [19], there is a clear need for more theory-based solutions.

As a contribution to our understanding of the Solow model and conditional convergence on the theoretical level, this paper derives the first-order approximated paths of two types of capital when both are separately incorporated into the production function. Given the popularity enjoyed by the Solow model and growth models at large, surprisingly little attention has been paid to mechanics of capital accumulation, possibly because of difficulties involved in measurement of the capital stock. One notable exception is a series of study investigating movements of the economy's capital-output ratio [14], [20]; yet, their analyses are based on the speed of convergence equation, not the growth path of the capital-output ratio per se.

The capital growth paths derived in the present study have a vital policy implication in the sense that, depending on the technology possessed by the economy, injection into one type of capital has a significantly larger short-run growth effect than injection into the other type of capital; thus the former should be the injection target under publicly funded capital enhancement programs such as public sector projects and foreign aid. Equally importantly, the derived capital growth equations are empirically testable—provided that data on capital stock of the economy are available [21]. This means a potential for a new method to test conditional convergence.

Methods

In the empirically testable version of the neoclassical growth model with two types of capital [5], [11], an economy's production at time t assumes a Harrod-neutral technology represented by(1)where Y is output, K is the stock of physical capital, H is the stock of human capital, L is labour, and A is the level of technology. The Harrod-neutral technology was introduced so that when the economy-wide output is divided by effective labour AL, the term A disappears from the model to provide a simpler setting without affecting general results. The output elasticities of capital, α and β, can take any value between zero and one given that the sum of the two does not exceed the unity. The use of the aggregate production function is consistent with the view that human-capital can be interpreted as a public good [22], [23]. In addition, the assumption of the Cobb-Douglas technology has been shown to not affect the findings of the model [24].

In this model, the evolution of the two types of capital per effective labour AL are given, respectively, by(2)and(3)where k and h are the stocks of physical and human capital per effective labour, respectively; n and g are the growth rates of population and technology, respectively; and δ is the depreciation rate. Following the real-life evidence [2], the depreciation rates of physical capital and human capital are assumed to be identical. The saving rates sk and sh define the proportions of the economy's output that are reinvested into physical capital and human capital. Following Equations (2) and (3), the steady-state level of the capitals per effective labour are given by(4)and(5)Unlike the textbook case with only one type of capital [25], this model does not yield an exact growth path of the capitals because the system of non-linear differential equations with the form of Equations (2) and (3) does not yield analytical solutions. While it is possible to obtain numerical solutions, such an approach is not useful when qualitative properties of the system are the focus of investigation. For this reason, a first-order approximation is conducted around the steady state to analytically inspect the growth of the economy.

Now, let the steady-state values of k and h be k* and h*, respectively. Then, the first-order approximations of and around the steady state are given by(6)and(7)where the first terms of both equations are zero. The partial derivatives of the evolution of capital with respect to capital stock can be obtained from Equations (2) and (3) as(8)(9)(10)and(11)Here fk and fh are the first derivatives of the production function per effective labour, yf(k,h) = kαhβ, with respect to the relevant subscripts.

Finally, substituting Equations (8)(11) into Equations (6) and (7) yields(12)and(13)Because k* and h* in Equations (12) and (13) are the steady-state values of the respective capital, they are constants. Thus, these two equations can be simplified to a system of differential equations with a general form(14)and(15)where a11, a12, a21, a22, b1, b2 are all constant parameters. The solution to this system is widely known, and hence it is possible to obtain the approximate growth paths of both physical and human capital. It turns out that the solution to the system is given by(16)and(17)where new variables K and H is defined as(18)and(19)Equations (18) and (19) represent the entire distances of capital development from the initial values to the steady-state values.

The derivation of Equations (16) and (17) is given in Supporting Information S1.

Results and Discussion

The capital growth paths derived above offer the basis to analyse the short-run effect of capital injections. The partial derivatives of Equations (16) and (17) with respect to injections ak and ah are given by(20)(21)(22)and(23)where N≡(n+g+δ). The last terms of all four equations are the changes in the steady-state levels of capital attributable to the instantaneous increase in capital. Using Equations (4) and (5), they are given by(24)(25)(26)and(27)The fact that all four derivatives are positive is consistent with one of the main predictions of the neoclassical models: the higher the reinvestment rates, the higher the steady-state levels of capital.

The speed of capital evolution is also affected by the introduction of capital injections from outside the economy. Equations (16) and (17) yield the time derivatives of the level of physical and human capital as(28)and(29)Using these terms, the effects of capital injections on the speed of capital evolution are expressed as(30)(31)(32)and(33)Equations (20)(23) and (30)(33) offer an insight about the role (or the lack thereof) of capital injection in economic growth. If the physical capital elasticity of production, α, is larger than the human capital elasticity of production, β, a one-off injection on physical infrastructure, ak, has positive growth effects on the stock levels of both physical and human capital—net of the permanent growth effect attributed to the increase in the steady-state level of capital. Conversely, an injection on social infrastructure, ah, shows negative effects on both types of capital stocks once the permanent effect has been translated into the economy. The situation is the opposite when β>α. Figures 1 and 2 show this point diagrammatically.

thumbnail
Figure 1. Capital growth premium: aid effect on capital stock.

Equation (20) can be summarised as , of which the terms and are constants. It holds that if α>β; from Equation (24), it also holds that as well. Thus, once the economy has received the permanent effect of foreign aid on k attributable to the change in its steady-state level, , the scale of the remaining effect, hereby called the growth premium rewarding the ‘correct’ allocation of aid resource, is proportional to the term irrespective of the magnitude of the coefficient . The situation is same for and opposite (showing the negative effect of the same absolute value) for and . The diagram shows a sample case where N = 0.05 and α+β = 0.8.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0049484.g001

thumbnail
Figure 2. Capital growth premium: aid effect on capital formation.

Equation (30) can be summarised as , of which the term is constant and, if α>β, positive. Thus, the effect of foreign aid on the speed of capital growth is proportional to irrespective of the magnitude of the coefficient . Equivalently, the curve shown in the present figure can also be derived by taking the time derivative of the curve shown in Figure 1. The situation is same for and opposite (showing the negative effect of the same absolute value) for and . The diagram shows a sample case where N = 0.05 and α+β = 0.8.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0049484.g002

Proposition: In the neoclassical world with two types of capital stock, capital injection from outside the economy to enhance one type of capital has a larger short-term effect than capital injection to enhance the other type of capital on the growth of both types of capital. Which type of capital shows the larger effect depends on the relative values of the capital elasticities of production.

The existence of ‘strong’ and ‘weak’ capitals in an economy may give a partial explanation as to why the literature is divided about the effect of foreign aid on economic growth [26]. In both extremes, there are two distinct views that foreign aid unconditionally facilitates economic growth [27][29] and that foreign aid does not facilitate economic growth [30][33]. In an attempt to break the deadlock, theories have been proposed to characterise conditions under which aid facilitates growth [34], [35] although they too have been challenged [36]. Thus, it is highly inconclusive whether there exists a nexus between aid and growth [37] and there is a clear need for more theoretical work [29] as well as empirical work.

The majority of these preceding studies investigate the relationship between aid and growth by means of aid-growth regression. The finding of the present study suggests that if the country in question happens to be receiving a significant portion of the ‘wrong’ kind of aid into the weak type of capital, foreign aid will unlikely show statistical significance regardless of the amount.

In other words, aid programs that enhance the strong type of capital have strictly superior short-term effects than those that enhance the weak type of capital without compromising any long-term effect. While these temporary effects will eventually converge to zero, it is noteworthy that the purpose of foreign aid is to assist the recipient countries for a short term; eventual convergence and catch-up are assumed implicitly. Meanwhile, it is Pareto-efficient for donors to offer the ‘right’ kind of aid: for example more infrastructure to capital intensive economies and more training programs to labour intensive economies.

Author Contributions

Analyzed the data: TT. Wrote the paper: TT.

References

  1. 1. Solow R (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quart J Econ 70: 65–94.
  2. 2. Carstensen K, Gundlach E, Hartmann S (2009) The augmented Solow model with Mincerian schooling and externalities. Germ Econ Rev 10: 448–463.
  3. 3. Jensen BS, Wong KY (1997) Dynamics, economic growth, and international trade. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. 384 p.
  4. 4. Fiaschi D, Lavezzi AM (2007) Appropriate technology in a Solovian nonlinear growth model. Oxford Rev Econ Pol 23: 115–133.
  5. 5. Gundlach E (2007) The Solow model in the empirics of growth and trade. Oxford Rev Econ Pol 23: 25–44.
  6. 6. Kemp MC, Long NV (2009) Extracting resource deposits of unknown size: optimal order. Germ Econ Rev 10: 401–421.
  7. 7. Merton RC (1975) An asymptotic theory of growth under uncertainty. Rev Econ Stud 42: 375–393.
  8. 8. Jensen BS, Larsen ME (2005) General equilibrium dynamics of multi-sector growth models. J Econ 10S: 17–56.
  9. 9. La Grandville Od (2007) The 1956 contribution to economic growth theory by Robert Solow: a major landmark and some of its undiscovered riches. Oxford Rev Econ Pol 23: 15–24.
  10. 10. Aghion P, Howitt P (2007) Capital, innovation, and growth accounting. Oxford Rev Econ Pol 23: 79–93.
  11. 11. Mankiw NG, David R, Weil D (1992) A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Quart J Econ 107: 407–437.
  12. 12. Galor O (1996) Convergence? Inferences from theoretical models. Econ J 106: 1056–69.
  13. 13. Galor O, Weil D (2000) Population, technology, and growth: from Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. Amer Econ Rev 90: 806–28.
  14. 14. McQuinn K, Whelan K (2007) Conditional convergence and the dynamics of the capital-output ratio. J Econ Growth 12: 159–184.
  15. 15. Nickell S (1981) Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica 49: 1417–26.
  16. 16. Bond S, Hoeffler A, Temple J (2001) GMM estimation of empirical growth models. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3048.
  17. 17. Barro R, Mankiw NG, Sala-i-Martin X (1995) Capital mobility in neoclassical models of growth. Amer Econ Rev 85: 103–15.
  18. 18. Caselli F, Esquivel G, Lefort F (1996) Reopening the convergence debate, a new look at cross-country growth empirics. J Econ Growth 1: 363–89.
  19. 19. Islam N (1995) Growth empirics, a panel data approach. Quart J Econ 110: 1127–70.
  20. 20. Hall R, Jones CI (1997) Why do some countries produce so much more per worker than others? Quart J Econ 114: 83–116.
  21. 21. Heston A, Summers R, Aten B (2002) Penn World Table Version 6.1. Philadelphia: Center for International Comparisons, the University of Pennsylvania.
  22. 22. Azariadis C, Drazen A (1990) Threshold externalities in economic development. Quart J Econ 105: 501–26.
  23. 23. Rauch JE (1993) Does history matter only when it matters little? The case of city-industry location. Quart J Econ 108: 843–67.
  24. 24. Jensen BS (2003) Walrasian general equilibrium allocations and dynamics in two-sector growth models. Germ Econ Rev 4: 53–87.
  25. 25. Barro RJ, Sala-i-Martin X (1995) Economic growth. New York: McGraw-Hill. 539 p.
  26. 26. Doucouliagos H, Paldam M (2008) Aid effectiveness on growth: a meta study. Eur J Polit Econ 24: 1–24.
  27. 27. White H (1992) The macroeconomic impact of development aid: a critical survey. J Dev Stud 28: 163–240.
  28. 28. Hansen H, Tarp F (2000) Aid effectiveness disputed. J Int Dev 12: 375–98.
  29. 29. Hansen H, Tarp F (2001) Aid and growth regressions. J Dev Econ 64: 547–70.
  30. 30. Boone P (1996) Politics and the effectiveness of foreign aid. Eur Econ Rev 40: 289–329.
  31. 31. Dawson PJ, Tiffin R (1999) Is there a long-run relationship between ODA and GDP?: the case of India. Appl Econ Lett 6: 275–77.
  32. 32. Rajan RG, Subramanian A (2008) Aid and growth: what does the cross-country evidence really show? Rev Econ Stat 90: 643–665.
  33. 33. Doucouliagos H, Paldam M (2009) The aid effectiveness literature: the sad results of 40 years of research. J Econ Surv 23: 433–461.
  34. 34. Burnside C, Dollar D (2000) Aid, policies, and growth. Amer Econ Rev 90: 847–68.
  35. 35. Dalgaard CJ, Hansen H, Tarp F (2004) On the empirics of foreign aid and growth. Econ J 114: F191–F216.
  36. 36. Easterly W, Levine R, Roodman D (2004) Aid, policies, and growth: comment. Amer Econ Rev 94: 774–780.
  37. 37. Roodman D (2007) The anarchy of numbers: aid, development, and cross-country empirics. World Bank Econ Rev 21: 255–277.