Skip to main content
Advertisement
Browse Subject Areas
?

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here.

  • Loading metrics

Social learning under acute stress

  • Lubomír Cingl

    Roles Conceptualization, Data curation, Formal analysis, Funding acquisition, Investigation, Methodology, Project administration, Resources, Software, Supervision, Validation, Visualization, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing

    lubomir.cingl@vse.cz

    Affiliation Department of Institutional, Environmental and Experimental Economics, Faculty of Economics, University of Economics in Prague, Prague, Czech Republic

Abstract

Individual decisions are often made simultaneously under social influence and acute stress, yet despite its importance, it has been largely unknown how stress influences the weight which people place on others’ decisions. To answer this I ran a laboratory experiment where 140 subjects were exposed to an acute stressor or a control procedure, immediately before and after which we tested their behavior in a simple Bayesian-updating task. Using three measures (cortisol, heart-rate and mood questionnaire) I show that subjects in the treatment group were under considerable levels of stress. Although stress was expected to increase the weight they put on information coming from the observation of others, I see no effect of stress on subjects’ behavior, either after private or public signals, or on the precision of the updating behavior. This holds across different specifications and after the addition of various personal controls, including the Big-Five personality traits and the psychological measure of conformity.

1. Introduction

The effects of social interaction on individual decision making are ubiquitous—be it the "lemming-like" behavior of investors in financial markets, teenagers’ experiments with illicit drugs, conforming to peers at school, or purchase behavior according to fads, fashion and top-10 lists [13]. Moreover, choices in social context are often made under acute stress. Traders, lawyers, politicians, and other professionals as well as many ordinary people regularly have to make decisions under severe pressure while being exposed to the social influence of others, for example when deciding in a group. Despite its importance, how stress affects the way people learn from social interactions is still largely unknown. Consider for example a bursting bubble in a financial market, when traders are in a situation where they need to quickly decide about enormous amounts of money on the basis of information from either objective sources like a technical analysis, or from what all the other traders are doing. If they tend to be influenced more by others’ behavior in the times of stress, thus overreacting to the stimuli and deepening the crisis [4], it may bring huge consequences: since their trading behavior influences world market prices, which are crucial for the stability and growth of economies, their overreactions eventually affect the wellbeing of consumers worldwide. Moreover, as an instinctive reaction stress cannot be controlled by human will while it has been shown to seriously affect behavior [5].

This paper is one of the first studies that clearly identify the causal effects of acute stress on individual social learning, although the effects of acute stress on other dimensions of social behavior have already been investigated, including variants of prosocial behavior [610], sensitivity to irrelevant social feedback [7], in-group vs. out-group affiliation [8], self-other distinction [11], conformity to higher rank in Navy [12], and the choice of strategy in a duopoly game [13]. Using observational data, the isolation of the causal effect is highly problematic especially in case of studying social learning and conformity as they may be influenced by many confounding factors that humans take into account when deciding whom to learn from, like the role of prestige, kin relationship, and the reputation of success [14,15]. Therefore, I run a laboratory experiment which creates the environment that I have full control over.

The influence of others on one’s decisions resulting in a convergent social behavior has been labeled differently in different disciplines, be it social learning, herding, group-mind, crowd- or mob-behavior, social imitation or mimicry [16]. In economics this phenomenon has mostly been studied in the context of herding in financial markets [1722], online-product choice [23,24], peer effects [25] and social learning [26,27]. The peers’ influence on decision-maker can generally be divided into two channels [25,28]: (i) direct learning from observing the peers’ choice (social learning) and (ii) a direct utility gain from the same (or similar) behavior (social utility). The social learning channel consists of just a bounded rational use of information a decision-maker obtains from the observation of the decisions of others and all behavioral biases are neglected. The social utility channel can be extended to comprise not only the natural preference for conformity [29,30], but also various social and psychological factors such as personality type [31,32] while it excludes any learning factors. As an example of what personal attributes may particularly matter, Baddeley et al. [33] identified that a younger female with high scores in the personality traits venturesomeness and impulsivity has a higher probability of following others in her decisions. In this paper I focus solely on the social learning channel while controlling for the role of selected personal attributes.

Paradigms used in the experimental literature for the measurement of social learning range from a simple prediction of judgment of others [34], a multiple-cue probability learning paradigm [35], to settings testing different learning strategies in Bayesian-updating processes [36]. In economics, information cascades hold a prominent place due to having a solid theoretical background [2,3741] and having been extensively experimentally [4244] and empirically [20,45] tested. In the information cascades setting, a series of individuals make a binary decisions over an unobserved state of the world based on imperfect information private to them, and on the observation of decisions made by others earlier in the sequence.

To test the representativeness heuristics [46] against the predictions of Bayes’ rule, Grether [47,48] designed an even simpler probabilistic task that unlike the information cascade setting does not contain the element of making decisions in a sequence. It is useful as it allows for a precise calculation of the optimal reaction to a new signal (information updating) according to the Bayes formula, but does not contain any other features that would potentially complicate the decision making procedure of subjects. It has been frequently employed in the literature to test deviations of human updating behavior due to various psychological biases, like apart from the above mentioned representativeness heuristics, the reinforcement heuristics [49], confirmation bias [50], general behavioral strategies [51], the role of reaction time [52], and has been even used as a suggested task for teaching the Bayes’ rule in the classroom [53]. Therefore I considered this task to be optimal for the purpose of my study.

In my operationalization of Grether’s task, subjects state subjective probability of which of the two unobserved states of the world is more likely to have occurred, and repeatedly restate it based on a series of first private and then public signals. They are incentivized in each decision to make a correct prediction. The structure and intensity of the signals differ across rounds but are the same for the treatment and control subjects in a given round. As has been shown that learning under stress may be impaired [54,55], I implemented a series of rounds before and after the treatment manipulation, which leads to a difference-in-differences econometrical approach.

The task setting allows for the examination of the difference between the treatment and the control group along several dimensions. The main aim of the study is to estimate the stress-induced difference in social learning that is captured by the updating behavior after receiving a public signal. Apart from that, I also examine the stress effect on general updating behavior that is revealed by the behavior after the private signals, and the general precision of subjectively stated probabilities compared to the predictions calculated using Bayes’ rule. As the control variables I employ the Bayes prediction that allows me to compare the reactions to the same strength of signal, personality profile as measured along the Big-5 dimensions [56,57], conformity [58], gender and age.

I work with the definition of acute stress as the physiological, psychological and behavioral reaction arising from perceived environmental demands threatening an important goal of an organism [59,60]. Generally speaking, an individual’s reaction to stress seems to be highly complex and to differ with respect to the type and duration of stressor [61] as well as with respect to various individual characteristics [62,63] and has been subjected to a number of models [60,64,65]. To induce acute stress I employ the Trier Social Stress Test for Groups [66,67] which consists of a stress-inducing or a control procedure that differ only in the stressful aspects, while cognitively are almost identical. The type of stress it induces in subjects, the acute psycho-social stress, seems to be the most common type of stress experienced by the general public in the workplace which enhances the external validity of the results in contrast to manipulations inducing a physical or pure psychological stress [65,68]. The peak of the cortisol response occurs 20 to 40 minutes after the start of the stressor and the whole cortisol response lasts 40 to 60 minutes after the stressor ceases [69,70]. I use this fact in the experimental design when the behavioral task is administered right after the end of the stress procedure when the stress response should be the highest and should last over the whole decision-making procedure.

As to studies focusing on social learning under stress, conformity under stress has already been studied but stress was induced rather indirectly: the authors experimentally tested conformity within the ranks of male U.S. Navy students under the threat of tear-gas infusion into the room [12]. Both the high and low status subjects behaved in a similar manner and became more willing to accept the opinion of their partner. Unfortunately, the authors do not provide any evidence that the subjects were under stress and their measure of conformity is rather crude. In another study subjects were exposed to time pressure while their cortisol and heart rate were measured [13]. Such manipulation is normally used in order to produce intuitive responses rather than stress. The authors argue that because the cortisol levels slightly increased, their manipulation was successful and they generally find more imitation relative to control. Lastly they show that subjects with higher physiological responses are more likely to imitate the choices of others, though with no difference across the treatments.

I hypothesized that stress would affect the social learning channel and people would become more receptive to the social information. Evolutionarily, stress seems to have developed to enhance the chance of survival that in the case of a collective species is closely connected with the survival of others. Coordinated actions among the group, like in case of fight-or-flight reaction [71] escaping a predator or fighting it collectively should increase the chance of survival of all members of the group [72,73]. I study if this instinct spills over to the decision making in a rather abstract context, which could however be then well generalized to other areas of decision making. One of the physiological effects of acute stress is the down-regulation of prefrontal cortex activity [63,7476]. Prefrontal cortex is generally known to be the centre of executive and cognitive control and willpower [77,78], particularly the medial part of prefrontal cortex is associated with social behavior as has been shown in a number of autism studies [79] and studies using fMRI [8082]. With the expected deterioration of higher cognitive abilities I hypothesized that the precision of the reaction to a new signal would decline under stress. Apart from the precision of estimates, the experimental design also allows for investigation of general updating behavior from objective sources that may also be affected due to the deterioration of cognitive abilities. Stress may further cause a shift in risk-preferences [74,8385] which may demonstrate in generally more conservative strategies, although the literature is far from any consensus on the effects of acute stress on risk-preferences. Moreover, other behavioral and psychological traits important to herding behavior may be affected by stress as well: even though personality traits are considered stable under stress [67], their interaction with stress may produce a situation when the resulting behavior is different for individuals high or low in the particular trait, such as in case of trait anxiety and competitive confidence [86]. Here I measure the Big-Five personality traits [87] and a conformity profile to capture such possible effects. Last, at least two related studies examined the rate of imitation under high levels of time pressure to find signs of more imitation [13,88]. Because time pressure may induce stress and its effect is then combined with lack of time making subjects decide intuitively, this evidence point in the direction of finding more social influence under stress.

2. Materials and methods

2.1. Task: Bayesian updating

In this section I describe in detail the task I use for the measurement of Bayesian updating that is based on Anderson and Holt [42] and Grether [47,48]. Since the task is quite complex, I first describe the general procedure in a given round, next I introduce the payment procedure as well as its pros and cons, and lastly I explain the structure of public signals. For the precise instructions given to the participants please refer to the Supplementary Online Material (SOM) S3 File.

In the task, subjects state their subjective beliefs about which of the two possible states of the world occurred based on signals they receive, and are monetarily rewarded for a correct prediction. The states of the world are framed as two possible unmarked bags containing marbles of two colors, blue and yellow. The “Yellow” bag contains more yellow marbles than blue marbles whereas in the “Blue” bag the ratio of the colors is symmetrically reversed. At the beginning of each round, one of the bags is randomly chosen by the computer with a 50% chance; the same bag for all participants in a given round. First of all, subjects are informed about the composition of the colors in both bags. With each new signal, subjects are asked to state or revise their beliefs using a slider that indicates a percentage probability of both outcomes (visualized in Fig 1). A private signal is the information about the color of a ball drawn with replacement from the chosen bag. After receiving several private signals and restating the subjective probability, always revealing color of just one ball at a time, participants are presented with the public signal in one of the forms described further. Public signal is essentially information about the decisions of some other randomly chosen players. The parameters (the ratio of the colors in bags as well as the number of private and public signals) varied across the rounds but stayed the same for all subjects in a given round, so that the situations where the public signal could overturn the content of the private signals (Table 1) would be maximized and also not a simple heuristics for the decision making could be developed.

thumbnail
Table 1. Round structure: Number of balls in the "Blue" bag.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.t001

thumbnail
Fig 1. The layout of the decision-making environment.

Note: The representation of the decision-making environment of the subjects. The left part of the Fig shows the decision after the arrival of the first private signal (top-left corner). The right part of the Fig shows the representation of public information in the upper right corner; particularly in the strategic form ("What if" scenario).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.g001

At the end of each round, subjects receive feedback on which bag was really chosen by the computer and how much ECU this round would pay if selected for payoff. Subjects were paid for each decision according to the quadratic scoring rule (QSR) for stating their beliefs in a given round, and all decisions in a given round added up to a total amount of ECU which could be earned from this round. In order to ease the cognitive demand required by understanding the rule [89], the QSR was explained and demonstrated by a table with selected probabilities and respective payments in the instructions. Moreover, as they moved the slider, the respective amount paid in case one of the bags was chosen changed in real time [90]. Prior to starting the task, subjects were informed that out of the 13 rounds, three would be randomly chosen for payoff at the end of the experiment.

QSR is one of very frequently applied methods for the incentivized elicitation of subjective probabilities [91]. The main concern is that it is incentive compatible only if the subjects are risk-neutral, which is commonly not the case as they are mostly risk-averse [92]. A risk-averse agent may want to hedge away from the extreme outcomes in order to minimize losses [93]. There are several methods that would allow the QSR under non-risk-neutrality to be truth-telling, such as paying small stakes, randomize payments or estimate the deviations from risk-neutrality (see e.g. review in [91]). However, for the purpose of a comparison of treatment intervention on two groups randomly created from the same population, we can reasonably assume that the distribution of risk-preferences and consequently the bias introduced by using QSR is on average the same in both of them. A potential confounding factor may arise if the treatment intervention changes also risk-preferences. For this purpose, an independently incentivized risk-elicitation task was implemented after the end of the Bayesian updating task (see the next section) and the potentially created confound is addressed in the Results section and in a detailed discussion in Section B in S1 File in SOM.

In each round after all private signals had been revealed, a public signal was presented. The public signal was conveyed by showing on-screen a small bag in the upper right corner of a blue or yellow color (see right part of Fig 1). The color of the small bag represented the color of the bag the other subject indicated to be more probable, rather than their point estimate. If the odds were 50/50, the color of the small bag was chosen randomly. One small bag indicated decision of one randomly chosen other participant. Participants either saw the color of the bag(s) and made a direct response, which was framed as "Scenario: Reality", or were presented with all possible combinations of the actions of others and were asked to state the probability conditionally for each situation. This strategy method was framed as the "Scenario: What if" and participants were paid only according to the situation that really occurred. Here also the order of the public signal was manipulated so that in five rounds the opposite signal to the current beliefs of participant was presented first, whereas a random order of the signals was implemented in another three rounds (Table 1). The strategy method also allowed for a richer set of observations with a given set of parameters than would be possible with the direct method only.

2.2. Task: Risk-preferences

To measure risk-preferences I used a standard multiple-price list task after Dohmen et al. [94] which was computerized using Z-Tree [95]. Subjects choose in ten situation either a safe payment or a lottery with equal probabilities of winning and not winning a fixed amount of 4000 ECU, and the safe payment starts at 0 ECU and gradually increases between the situations in steps of 300 ECU up to 2700 ECU. Subjects were informed that one situation would be selected at random and would be paid according to their decision in the selected round. A subject with consistent risk-preference profile should start with choosing lottery if the safe payment is 0 and at some point switch to the preference of the safe payment. This switching point is directly informative of the individual certainty equivalent and can be used as a proxy for the risk-profile of a participant. I allowed for an inconsistent behavior by allowing subjects to choose freely in any pair of actions. The effect of treatment manipulation on risk-preferences is discussed in a different article [96] where also the detailed instructions and the screenshot of the task can be found, while here the task serves only for the purpose of a robustness check.

2.3. Treatment manipulation: Stress-inducing procedure

Subjects were exposed to a slightly modified Trier Social Stress Test for Groups (TSST-G, [66]), which is a standardized psychological protocol for inducing acute psychosocial stress. The changes to the original protocol concerned mainly the information given to participants regarding the behavioral training of the panel members and regarding the fact that the video recordings would later be analyzed, so that no deception was present. The approval of the Institutional Review Board of the Laboratory of Experimental Economics, Faculty of Economics, University of Economics, Prague (IRB LEE 001–2012) was obtained prior to the experiment. The subjects were randomly divided into two groups of seven and after reading the instructions silently for 3 minutes, they went into two separate rooms adjacent to the lab that were set-up for the procedures. The TSST-G protocol consists of two parts: a public speaking and a mental arithmetic part. The stress condition frames these two parts as a mock job-interview and a serial subtraction of 17 from 4578, respectively, while in the control group subjects jointly read a scientific text aloud in a low voice, and said out loud numbers in steps of a certain magnitude, e.g. 5, 10, 15, 20 etc. After entering the room, the participants stood in places marked by their participant numbers, and had headphones with ambient noise on so that they would not hear each other. In the stress condition, two additional experimenters, who were referred to as a "committee" during the procedure, sat at a desk in front of the participants, wore white laboratory coats and had a video camera by their side. The committee had been trained not to give any feedback on the subjects’ performance either verbally or physically. With a neutral expression on their faces, they called subjects in a random order, who then had two minutes to present their job-interview. When all subjects had finished their job-interviews, the committee asked the subjects again one-by-one to complete the arithmetic task for one minute. The committee made notes during the whole procedure. A careful debriefing was carried out with the stress group before they received the payments at the end of the experiment. In the control condition, the two panel members were referred to as "assistants" and subjects were informed that their role was only to measure time and provide instructions for the next part of the procedure.

2.4. Sample & procedures

By using ORSEE [97] 140 healthy subjects were recruited: 67 females (mean age 22.1, SD = 2 years) and 73 males (mean age 22.6, SD = 2.7 years). The sessions were run in two batches with identical procedures, experimenters and committee members, therefore I pool the results. The first five sessions were run in April 2012 and the next five sessions in November 2014. Subjects were mostly students of economics, management or related disciplines (72%). I followed best practices in order to avoid any factors confounding cortisol measurement [98]: Subjects received an invitation email already with instructions to abstain from fatty food, nicotine and heavy exercise at least 2 hours prior to the experiment. Immediately before the experiment subjects were screened for any circumstances that could potentially disrupt the cortisol response: health status, drug intake, caffeine, heavy meals, and contraceptive intake. I then performed robustness checks and none of the problematic factors mattered for the main results (available upon request). With one exception the participants were all normal body-weight and twelve women indicated taking oral contraceptives. Out of these twelve women, five were assigned to the treatment group; two of these did not show the expected cortisol increase.

Subjects were not notified about the purpose of the experiment beforehand in order to minimize the selection bias. They signed an informed consent form which referred to the treatment procedure as a "challenge" task and were specifically and repeatedly informed about the chance to leave the experiment at any point in time. None decided to leave before the regular end of the experiment.

All experimental payoffs were denominated in experimental currency units (ECUs) and were converted to Czech crowns at the end of the experiment at a conversion rate 32 ECU = 1 CZK. The experiment lasted on average a little less than 2.5 hours and was conducted in English. All subjects were listed in the database for experiments conducted in English and indicated no difficulties understanding the instructions or speaking. One experimental session included 14 subjects (seven in the treatment and seven in the control group), two experimenters and four members of the committee for the TSST-G procedure. All sessions started at 16:30 in order to make the cortisol measurement comparable across sessions due to the natural diurnal cortisol cycle. The average payoff was 490 CZK, i.e. 19.6 EUR.

The timeline of the experiment is summarized in Fig 2. After arriving at the laboratory subjects were randomly assigned to computers, signed the consent form and the general instructions were read aloud by the experimenter. Participants got the heart-rate monitors attached, and were asked to fill-in an on-screen questionnaire assessing their personality profile. The instructions for the probabilistic task were then read aloud and subjects had to answer three questions confirming their understanding. Then they had two trial and five real rounds of the task. At this point they were asked to give the first sample of saliva and fill in the first part of the MDM questionnaire. Instructions to the TSST-G treatment and control procedure were distributed next. Participants read them silently and had few minutes to either prepare for the job interview or for reading a scientific text which was subsequently performed in adjacent separate rooms, i.e. the full TSST-G treatment and control procedures were carried out. After this, the participants returned to the lab, were seated back at computers, the second sample of saliva was collected and they filled in the second part of the MDM questionnaire. Then the participants were to solve eight more rounds of the previous task. When finished, the participants gave their third saliva sample and completed a separately paid-for task aimed at measuring their risk-preferences. At the end of the experiment, three rounds of the task were randomly drawn for payment, subjects completed a short questionnaire on their personal characteristics and proceeded to payment. All subjects were paid in private, and when the control group had left the laboratory, a thorough debriefing of the TSST-G procedure was carried out with the treatment group. Participants were asked to sign a statement of confidentiality with respect to the experimental procedure.

2.5. Questionnaires—Personality measurement

Participants filled in the 50-item set of IPIP Big-Five Factor Markers [57] which is a measure of the five major factors of personality, openness to experience, conscientiousness, extraversion, agreeableness and neuroticism. In addition to that, I included a conformity inventory IPIP measuring construct similar to the revised Jackson Personality Inventory [58] to control for the natural behavioral propensity to conform to the opinion of others.

3. Results

3.1. Randomization check

I perform a randomization check of observable characteristics that may influence the stated probability after public signals. Table A1 in the S1 File in SOM shows that the treatment and control groups were balanced with respect to gender, age and education. Further factors that may influence the results are the "Big-5" personality traits and conformity. The treatment group was higher in extraversion and neuroticism, while not statistically different in the other dimensions, which is another reason to add these controls to the regression analysis, apart from controlling for the behavioral explanation of the social influence.

3.2. Manipulation check

Using three measures I show that stress induction was successful. First I present in panel (a) of Fig 3 the cortisol reaction that I consider to be the most reliable indicator of induced stress. The level of concentration of salivary cortisol is not different for the treatment and control groups before the TSST-G procedure (two-sample Wilcoxon ranksum test: z = -0.21, p = 0.83, d = -0.1; reported effect sizes are Cohen’s d, corrected for uneven groups.), but the sample taken after the procedure as well as the sample taken after the end of the task show a significant increase for the treatment group (z = -6.22, p < 0.001, d = -1.1 and z = -6.05, p < 0.001, d = -1.04, respectively).

thumbnail
Fig 3. Induced stress reaction: Cortisol and heart-rate.

Notes: The darker color indicates the treatment group. Panel (a): Mean levels of free salivary cortisol; Sample 1 was collected before the treatment or control TSST-G procedure, sample 2 after the TSST-G procedure and sample 3 before the risk task. Panel (b): Mean levels of heart-rate calculated from individual averages over the time periods before, during and after the TSST-G procedure. Error bars indicate standard errors of the mean.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.g003

Second, panel (b) of Fig 3 summarizes the heart-rate before, during and after the stress procedure. I note that there were technical problems with measurement in several subjects. With some we were completely unable to find the signal while with others the signal kept turning on and off during the procedure; therefore I do not have a full number of observations for this measure. Heart-rate does not differ between the treatment and control groups before (z = -0.77, p = 0.44, d = -0.14) and after (z = -0.99, p = 0.32, d = -0.12) the TSST-G procedure, however, there is a significant difference during the procedure (z = -1.84, p = 0.066, d = -0.41) which supports the claim that subjects in the treatment group were physiologically under stress.

The subjective effect of stress was captured by the change in the subjects’ mood reported in the MDM questionnaire. Panel (a) of Fig 4 shows that before the treatment procedure, the treatment and control groups’ scores were not different in any of the three dimensions ("good-bad": z = -1.05; p = 0.29; d = -0.11; "awake-tired": z = -0.83; p = 0.83; d = -0.00; "calm-nervous": z = -1.2; p = 0.23; d = -1.12). Panel (b) of Fig 4 reveals that after the TSST-G procedure, the treatment group reported scores significantly different than the control group: the treatment group scored closer to the "bad" (z = 3.60; p < 0.001; d = 0.68) and the "nervous" (z = 3.44; p < 0.001; d = 0.61) dimensions. The last "awake-tired" dimension was not different across the two groups (z = -1.59; p = 0.11; d = -0.1). This finding shows that subjects in the treatment group were also under psychological stress. For further details see Table A2 in S1 File with the descriptive statistics of all three variables further divided by gender.

thumbnail
Fig 4. Induced stress reaction: Mood.

Notes: Mood before (panel a) and after (panel b) the TSST-G procedure—scores from the Multidimensional Mood State Questionnaire. The darker color indicates the treatment group. Error bars indicate standard errors of the mean.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.g004

The changes of the two physiological measures (cortisol and heart-rate) are significantly correlated, (ρ = 0.385; p < 0.001). The cortisol response is further correlated with the MDM score in the good-bad dimension (ρ = -0.259; p < 0.01) and in the calm-nervous dimension (ρ = -0.23; p < 0.01). The association of heart-rate and psychological measures is significant in the calm-nervous dimension (ρ = -0.21; p = 0.02) and the awake-tired dimension (ρ = 0.15; p = 0.09). The three mood dimensions are further highly correlated, as could be expected.

3.3. Social learning

The variable of interest in the analysis, Decision, is the stated probability entered by subjects after each new signal using a slider that they moved from the initial point 50/50. I take the value of the distance from the 50/50 point to the new position of the slider in the direction of the new signal. Apart from the actual decision of the subjects I also calculate the optimal decision (variable “True”), given all information a subject had received prior to the current decision in a given round, i.e. the number, direction and strength of all preceding signals. While calculating True I assume that a decision maker is rational in that she uses the Bayes formula for updating her priors and disregards any irrelevant information in the sense that there is no interdependence between the answers in the "What-if" scenario and between the rounds. I am aware of the on-going debate as to whether people really use the Bayes formula in their decision making and thus I note that it is a rather simplified assumption made for the sake of convenience. The calculation of True was done in the following manner: let’s define b the number of blue balls in the Blue bag, y the number of yellow balls in the Yellow bag, and n the total number of the balls in the bag. The optimal move after the first signal, which was always private, was calculated by first finding the probability of drawing a blue ball given the composition: Pr(b|B) = b/n. The probability of drawing the yellow ball is complementary, i.e. Pr(y|B) = 1 − b/n. The value of True is the probability of the bag being Blue, given this signal, which is . See Section D in S1 File in SOM for further details about the calculation of True for more complicated private and public signals. For the calculation of the public signals I assume that subjects also took into account the possibility that when the other subjects stated exactly the same probabilities of both bags having been selected, the resulting signal was chosen at random.

Next I define a new variable Difference as the difference between Decision and True, which then shows whether subjects over- or under-valued the signal compared to the True value, if the Decision was higher or lower than the True, respectively. Recall that True captures the informational content of the signals, therefore also the composition of the bag, number of signals received and the share of signals for the chosen color. Table A3 in S1 File provides the descriptive statistics of the main independent variables used in the analysis.

Fig 5 illustrates that subjects suffered from typical behavioral biases identified in the literature, such as stating more likely probabilities rounded to 5 or 10 and being reluctant to state the probability closer to the extreme, when contrasted with the True probability.

When examining the density of the variable Difference, it reveals that the subjects reacted rather rationally to the signals they had received since the distribution is centered on the mean of zero and is not skewed to either of the sides. When divided into the two types of signals after treatment (Fig 6), qualitatively no difference emerges.

thumbnail
Fig 6. Histogram of variable Difference, by the type of signal and treatment status.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.g006

3.4. Regression analysis

Since I observe the decisions of both groups before and after the treatment manipulation, I analyze the level differences using the difference-in-differences approach, even though accounting for the behavior before the treatment intervention may be considered as an overly conservative approach. Both treatment and control groups faced identical structure of signals in a given round, so on average they faced signals of the same strength and in the same order. The analysis is thus first comparing only the average reactions of the treatment and the control groups across the two periods, while I analyze the role of time dimension together with other robustness checks in more detail in the latter sections. To account for the potential correlation between decisions made by a single individual, I cluster standard errors in the regressions on an individual level.

Table 2 presents the main results of the regression analysis. There I regress the variable Decision on Treatment dummy, the dummy indicating decisions made after the treatment procedure Round after stress, and their interaction Treatment X Round after TSST, which constitutes the standard difference-in-differences setting. To investigate the differential reaction to private and public signals, I further include the following set of variables: Public is a dummy indicating the public signal, Public X Treatment indicates decisions of subjects in the treatment group when reacting to public signals, Public X Round after TSST indicates the decisions made in reaction to public signals after the treatment procedure, and the triple interaction Public X Round after TSST X Treatment is the coefficient of interest as it indicates how different before and after the treatment intervention a reaction to a public compared to private signal between the treatment and control group. After running the baseline model, I add the session fixed effects to account for the unobserved heterogeneity across sessions (column 2). In column 3 I add the individual observable characteristics, i.e. the Big-Five personality traits, age, the trait conformity, and a dummy indicating female. In column 4 I finally add a set of variables that should reveal a differential reaction of treatment group after the treatment intervention to signals of the same strength. The coefficient of interest is again the triple interaction True X Round after TSST X Treatment.

thumbnail
Table 2. Regression analysis, dependent variable Decision.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.t002

The results generally show a robust null effect. First note that the coefficient of the variable Treatment X Round after stress is not different from zero in any of the specifications (all p’s > 0.36), which informs us that the general weight of either type of a signal was not different for both treatment and the control groups after the TSST-G procedure. Its largest magnitude -0.199 corresponds to about 0.01 SD. Next the coefficient of the triple interaction Public X Round after TSST X Treatment is also not significantly different from zero which implies that the weight of public signals after the TSST-G procedure was not different in the treatment and the control groups. The significant and positive coefficient of the indicator variable Public informs us that the signal from public sources followed by about 2.7 points more than the private signal, which is actually inconsistent with the literature [99,100] where the typical finding is that people tend to rely more on private than on public information. The significance of the control variable True shows that subjects used the information contained in the signals, and for each percentage point in the probability predicted by the Bayes formula they moved the slider on average by 0.37 points in the correct direction. The triple interaction term True X Round after TSST X Treatment is insignificant and small in magnitude, which suggests that the difference between the treatment and control group in the how they react to the strength of signals did not change compared to the situation before the treatment intervention. Further note the insignificance of the term Treatment reveals that there are no systematic differences between the two groups before the treatment intervention and the term Round after stress shows no difference between the decisions made before the treatment procedure and after the procedure in the control group. From the control variables, coefficient of Age is significant and positive, which means that older subjects stated probability after a private signal larger than the younger ones.

For a better clarity I present in the SOM the analysis re-run only on decisions made after the private (Table A4 in S1 File) and only public (Table A5 in S1 File) signals, where I also show the coefficients of the control variables. Personality traits are insignificant with the exception of Neuroticism (and for public signals, also Agreeableness) which is significant on a 1% level and negative, which means that subjects that are more neurotic and emotionally unstable stated a probability smaller than other subjects. Also, coefficient of Age is significant and positive, which informs us that generally older subjects tend to state higher stated probability. In addition to the analysis above I also test a gender-specific effect of the treatment by adding a set of dummy variables Female, Treatment X Female and Treatment X Female X Round after stress (column 3 in both tables). The triple interaction is not significant in any of the two tables, and the coefficient of Treatment X Round after stress also does not change. Finally I test for an order effect (column 6) when I restrict the observations to only the first private or public signals each subject received in a given round to conclude that there was no difference. Even then the coefficient of Treatment *Round after stress does not change its size or significance.

3.5. Precision of estimates

Another potential effect of stress was hypothesized to appear in the precision of individual estimates relative to the value predicted by the Bayes theorem. Using again the same difference-in-differences approach I regress the variable Difference in an absolute value on the sets of variables as in the preceding sections, only separately for private and public signals. In Table 3 I show that for both types of the signal, I cannot reject that the precision of estimates is the same for both treatment and control groups since the coefficient of Treatment *Round after stress is not significantly different from zero in all specifications. The coefficient Round after stress is significant and negative for the decisions made after the public signal which shows that both treatment and control groups improved the precision of the estimates after the TSST-G procedure. The addition of personality controls (columns 3 and 7) does not change anything. When investigating the role of the size of the Bayesian prediction by adding variable True and the appropriate set of interactions for the diff-in-diff-in-diff, we observe the triple interaction marginally significant (p = 0.078) and positive for the private signals (column 4) which means that the precision of subjects in treatment group was relatively to the control group a little worse after the treatment intervention. For the public signals this relationship (column 8) however does not hold.

thumbnail
Table 3. Regression analysis, dependent variable Difference in absolute value.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.t003

3.6. Robustness checks

To investigate whether there were any different treatment effects with respect to the reactivity to stress, I also perform the difference-in-differences comparison of the cortisol responders and non-responders, where I define that a subject is a cortisol responder as 1 if cortisol increased by at least 1.5 nmol/l or 15.5% between the baseline (sample 1) and the higher of the two samples taken after the treatment procedure [101] (see Tables A6 and A7 in S1 File for the distribution of the responders in the treatment and control groups). I re-run the regression models in Tables 2 and 3 to conclude that the results are robust against this change of specification, which would reveal correlations between being stressed and a change in behavior (results in Table A8 in S1 File).

I further checked for a correlation between the cortisol increase and the variables of interest (Decision and Difference in absolute value) for the treatment group only to see that the interaction of the cortisol increase Responder with Round after stress is not significant. I then substitute the increase in cortisol with the change in heart-rate during the procedure, change in mood in the good-bad and the calm-nervous dimensions to see again no effect on any of the main variables of interest. Also when I investigate treatment-specific reaction with respect to observable personal controls and interact them with Treatment, results hold unchanged and none of the interactions is significant (Results available upon request).

Next, to account better for the time-dimension of decisions I re-run the analysis for the main specifications using random-effects panel data estimation with the unit-level being the individual and the time-dimension being the order of the decision made by an individual in an experiment; and still cluster the standard errors on the individual level. Table A9 in S1 File shows that again, no qualitative difference in the results emerges. Next I perform two more exercises where I take the main specifications and add two variables that represent the time dimension, the order number of the round and the order number of a single individual decision, and their interactions with Treatment. For a better clarity I restrict the analysis to the periods after the treatment intervention (proper randomization allows for this move) and in Tables A10 and A11 in S1 File I show that the coefficients of variables of interest remain unaffected.

As mentioned earlier, an important potential confounding factor is a treatment-specific change in risk-preferences, especially when the quadratic scoring rule is incentive compatible only under risk-neutrality. First note that the QSR procedure was constant across treatments and due to the random distribution of subjects into treatment and control we can reasonably assume a similar a-priori distribution of risk-preference profiles in both groups. Second, the increase in risk-aversion would probably induce more conservative updating behavior and subjects would generally keep the slider closer to the midpoint (hedge more), which is however not what is observed in the data. As I observe a null result, a potential change in risk-preferences may have offset the change in updating behavior. This effect may be revealed by controlling for the risk-preferences in the above-carried regressions, even though such move may introduce an endogeneity bias. Recall that risk-preference profiles were measured by the incentivized risk-elicitation task. For 136 subjects we elicit a meaningful certainty equivalent, as four subjects indicated inconsistent choices. In Table A12 in S1 File three key regression specifications are re-run with the addition of the Certainty equivalent. The results allow us to conclude that the main coefficient of interest of the diff-in-diff interaction does not change its magnitude or insignificance, and the role of risk-preference change seems irrelevant.

3.7. Variance analysis

To further check for possible differences in treatment effects I also conduct the analysis of the equality of variance between the treatment and control groups. The variance ratio test revealed no differences between the two groups in the variable Decision; either before (p = 0.94) or after (p = 0.77) the TSST-G procedure. The Kolmogorov-Smirnov test for the equality of distribution functions also showed no differences (corrected p-values: before, p = 0.18; after, p = 0.3).

When carried out for the variable Difference in absolute value, the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test revealed no difference before (corrected p = 0.36), but after (p = 0.013) the TSST-G procedure. When examined with the robust test for the equality of variances, the differences disappear (p > 0.37 and above). I implemented this test in Stata 12 in the command robvar, which uses the Levene’s robust statistic. Since the distribution is highly skewed (p<0.001), a standard test of the equality of variances would deliver biased results.

4. Discussion

The subjects in the treatment group were indeed physiologically and psychologically stressed: The success of the manipulation is demonstrated using two physiological (salivary cortisol levels and heart-rate) and one psychological (Multidimensional Mood Questionnaire scores, [102]) measures. I focus on salivary cortisol since it has been established as a reliable biomarker of the HPA activation during acute stress [103,104]. While not different between the groups during the baseline measurement, cortisol levels slightly decreased in the control group during the control procedure while they almost doubled in the treatment group. Heart-rate was on average 10 beats per minute higher for the treatment group than for the control group. The mood scores showed treatment group felt significantly worse and more nervous than the control group. Overall, these measures show that the magnitude of stress induced in subjects was in a comparable manner as in the related literature [66,70].

The main behavioral result stemming from an experiment with 140 subjects which is comparable or larger than what has typically been used in the literature [6,86,105], is that stress has robust null effect on social learning, i.e. the weight which both the public and private signals are given in the decisions of subjects is not statistically different between the treatment (stress) and the control (non-stress) groups. The precision of the individual point estimates also does not systematically differ, although in one specification the difference in precision after private signals between the treatment and control groups in the reaction to the signal strength (the Bayesian prediction) was larger after the treatment manipulation, but it was marginally significant (p = 0.078) and small in magnitude. This could be interpreted such that with stronger signals the treatment group made larger deviations from the optimal moves.

The general null result is robust to the addition of various control variables, including psychological measure of conformity and personality traits. Moreover, the data replicates common findings in the literature concerning the updating behavior as I observe common behavioral regularities, such as the clustering of probability estimates on multiples of five, conservativeness and an updating behavior generally consistent with the Bayes theorem [49,106,107]. I also find that public signal is generally taken into account more during updating and older subjects are more conservative than younger ones. From the personality traits only Neuroticism is consistently significant across specifications and negative in sign, which suggests that subjects high in this trait are also generally more conservative.

In the meta-analysis of information-cascade studies, Weizsäcker [99] finds that private signals are taken more seriously than public signals in a 2:1 ratio, while I observe an opposite finding. This could be due to several reasons. First, subjects could have really understood the signal as something more informative, which is however unlikely to have happened. Second, our calculation of the Bayesian benchmark included an assumption that in case of 50/50 a random color would be chosen, which could have been disregarded by subjects. Third, the mere fact that they were shown later in the sequence of all signals in a given round may have caused that they were taken more seriously than they should have been as the uncertainty over which bag had been selected was relatively small.

The absence of finding the hypothesized relationships may be due to several reasons. Either the design was too noisy and unable to correctly identify the proposed relationship, or the relationship is smaller than could be found with the statistical power in this design, or the relationship is indeed not there, or two opposing stress effects may have cancelled each other out [105]. I cannot rule out the last possibility since for example the change in preferences and change in expectations may have yielded opposing effects: subjects may have been more likely to take into account the information from the public signal due to a change in their preferences, but at the same time, since they knew others were also under stress and may have reacted to the new situations even more, they may have discounted their beliefs about the real value of public signal.

To check the statistical power of my design I first used G*POWER 3.1 [108] to assess the post-hoc statistical power of the t-tests in the multiple regression with four to thirteen predictors. The analysis revealed that with the sample size of 140 subjects and the power of 0.8, my design was able to detect a small to medium effect size of f2 = 0.044 to 0.06, depending on the specification (see Section C in S1 File in SOM for the output from G*POWER). The conventional values for the effect size in this test are for small effect f2 = 0.02, medium effect f2 = 0.15 and for large effect f2 = 0.35 [108,109]. Next I calculated the minimal detectable effect size as suggested by Haushofer & Shapiro [110]: with the power of the test of 0.8 and the significance level of 0.05, the post-hoc minimal detectable effect size is given by where t1−k is the t-statistic value required for obtaining 80% power, t(α/2) is the critical value required to achieve the 5% significance level, P is the fraction of the sample that was treated and the remaining fraction is the standard error of the coefficient of interest. With t1−k = 0.84, t(α/2) = 1.96 and P = 0.5 is thus , i.e. a simple multiple of the standard error of estimated coefficient of a standardized variable. This approach yields size of the effect between 0.14 and 0.16 SD (Table A13 in S1 File), which corresponds to a rather small effect size that was possible to detect with this design. Therefore it seems unlikely that the null result is due to insufficient power of the experimental design.

If stress causes changes in risk preferences, I should observe a systematic difference between the treatment and control groups after the treatment manipulation; i.e. the coefficient of the variable Treatment*Round after stress should be significantly different from zero. However, I do not observe any such effect. Either the effect is too small to be identified in the regressions, or it is already captured in some of the control variables, or it is offset by a combination of other factors, such as differences in beliefs about others and about the riskiness of the signals. Another potential reason may be hidden in the opposing effects of an increased reward responsiveness under stress [111] and increased risk aversion that cancel each other out. When controlling for the certainty equivalent in the regressions I show that this is unlikely to explain the null effects.

Another possible explanation for the null result could arise despite all my efforts to avoid it by implementing the design feature of constantly changing the setting of the parameters of the problem, the updating process in the task could have already been mastered in the rounds before the stress procedure. In such a case, the decision making process would be operated by the fast automatic, Type-I processes rather than by the slower Type-II, rational processes. Indeed, in a recent study Bayesian updating has been found to be governed rather by automatic processes than by rational thought [52]. If a stress reaction affects the higher-cognitive functions operated in the prefrontal cortex as is generally suggested in the literature [63,74,76], but does not impair habitual automatic behavior, my design was not able to capture the effects of stress on social learning initiated in the higher-order cognitive structures.

In the related literature investigating the effects of stress on economic decision making, the results in many domains are generally mixed and this is by far not the first study to find null effects. No effects of acute stress were found on inter-temporal discounting [105], non-social risk-taking [6], and ambiguity aversion [112]. However, other studies found positive results, e.g. in the realm of risk-preferences, willingness to compete or social preferences [6,9,55,84,96,113,114]. Moreover, the effects of stress can basically vary by the stressor used [115,116] and the timing when the behavioral task was administered [117], which may also explain why I observe different results than Buckert, Oechsler et al. [13].

5. Conclusion

As one of the first studies of this type in the literature, using an efficient stressor and a standard Bayesian updating task I provide evidence that there is no effect of acute stress on social learning. Using salivary cortisol levels, heart rate and changes in mood I demonstrate that unlike participants in the control group, participants in the treatment group were under considerable levels of stress. The use of information in the process of Bayesian updating as well as the precision of the subjective estimates does not differ for the participants who underwent a stress-inducing treatment procedure and the control participants, and this is true for both private and public signals they received. I further conduct several robustness checks to prove that this null result is not due to different reactions of stressed and non-stressed subjects in terms of the cortisol increase, different gender reactions to stress, differences in personality, and due to subject-specific and session-specific effects. My results thus suggest that despite the existing literature on the effects of acute stress on decision making [5], individual-level social learning behavior is not affected by mild acute psycho-social stress, though I cannot conclude the existence of effects of a more severe or a different type of stress [115].

If we assume that the daily routine behavior of decision makers, e.g. professional traders, is more a habitual than a higher cognitive activity, the results of this study imply that the observed real-world phenomena when people engage in social learning behavior in stressful situations, such as bank-runs, herding in financial markets during increased volatility and panic in general, as well as the results of the related studies [12,13], occur due to changes in a different dimension of human behavior than social learning and information updating, with the likely candidates being risk preferences, beliefs about the behavior of others and the general adaptation to a new environment. The real underlying reasons of these phenomena should thus be investigated in the future research.

Supporting information

S1 File. Additional results.

This file contains additional results referred to from the main text. It has sections labeled A to D. Section A contains 13 tables labeled Table A1 to Table A13; section B contains text discussing the role of risk preferences in detail; section C contains output from a program G-Power to support calculations made in the main text, and section D contains a detailed description of the calculation procedure of the variable True.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.s001

(PDF)

S2 File. TSST-G protocol.

This file contains a detailed description of the treatment procedure, including a scheme of the room, the script and instructions for both treatment and control groups, and the text used for the debriefing of the treatment group.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.s002

(PDF)

S3 File. Experimental instructions.

This file contains the instructions that were given to subjects about the task measuring the updating behavior that is described in the main text in section 3.1.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.s003

(PDF)

S4 File. Control questions.

This file includes the exact wording of the control questions that were checking the understanding of subjects to the rules of the main task.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.s004

(PDF)

S5 File. Datasets and do-files.

This compressed file includes the data as gathered in the experiment and do-files that produced the tables in the text. The datasets are in the Stata 13 format and are two for the sake of convenience of computation. The datafile S5_data_personality.dta and its associated do-file S5_do_personality.do were used for the production of the Tables A1 and A2 (manipulation and randomization checks). Datafile S5_data_main.dta and associated do-file S5_do_main.do were used for the production of the rest of the tables.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202335.s005

(ZIP)

Acknowledgments

This research was supported by Charles University Grant Agency grant GA UK No. 4046/11. I express thanks to Michal Bauer, Steffen Huck, Andrew Schotter, Arno Riedl, Matthias Sutter, Bertil Tungodden, Debrah Meloso, Peter Katuščák, Clémens Kirschbaum, Tereza Nekovářová, Barbara Pertold-Gebicka, Jozef Baruník, Maroš Servátka, Therese Nilsson, Vincenzo Merella, Libor Dušek, Klára Kalíšková, Štěpán Jurajda; and the audience at the Norwegian School of Economics and Nordic Conference on Experimental and Behavioral Economics 2016 for their help and valuable comments. The help of Jana Cahlíková during the execution of the experiment is particularly acknowledged. I would also like to thank Bernadette Von Dawans and Clémens Kirschbaum for the provision of the script of the manipulation procedure.

References

  1. 1. Zafar B. An experimental investigation of why individuals conform. Eur Econ Rev. Elsevier; 2011;55: 774–798.
  2. 2. Bikhchandani S, Hirshleifer D, Welch I. Learning from the Behavior of Others: Conformity, Fads, and Informational Cascades. J Econ Perspect. 1998;12: 151–170. Available: http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:aea:jecper:v:12:y:1998:i:3:p:151-70
  3. 3. Bikhchandani S, Sharma S. Herd behavior in financial markets. IMF Staff Pap. JSTOR; 2000; 279–310.
  4. 4. Coates JM, Herbert J. Endogenous steroids and financial risk taking on a London trading floor. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A. 2008;105: 6167–72. pmid:18413617
  5. 5. Starcke K, Brand M. Decision making under stress: A selective review. Neurosci Biobehav Rev. Elsevier Ltd; 2012;36: 1228–1248. pmid:22342781
  6. 6. von Dawans B, Fischbacher U, Kirschbaum C, Fehr E, Heinrichs M. The social dimension of stress reactivity: acute stress increases prosocial behavior in humans. Psychol Sci. 2012;23: 651–60. pmid:22593119
  7. 7. FeldmanHall O, Raio CM, Kubota JT, Seiler MG, Phelps EA. The Effects of Social Context and Acute Stress on Decision Making Under Uncertainty. Psychol Sci. 2015;26: 1918–1926. pmid:26546080
  8. 8. Steinbeis N, Engert V, Linz R, Singer T. The effects of stress and affiliation on social decision-making: Investigating the tend-and-befriend pattern. Psychoneuroendocrinology. Elsevier Ltd; 2015;62: 138–148. pmid:26311359
  9. 9. Vinkers CH, Zorn JV, Cornelisse S, Koot S, Houtepen LC, Olivier B, et al. Time-dependent changes in altruistic punishment following stress. Psychoneuroendocrinology. 2013;38: 1467–75. pmid:23375639
  10. 10. Tomova L, Majdandžić J, Hummer A, Windischberger C, Heinrichs M, Lamm C. Increased neural responses to empathy for pain might explain how acute stress increases prosociality. Soc Cogn Affect Neurosci. 2017;12: 401–408. pmid:27798249
  11. 11. Tomova L, von Dawans B, Heinrichs M, Silani G, Lamm C. Is stress affecting our ability to tune into others? Evidence for gender differences in the effects of stress on self-other distinction. Psychoneuroendocrinology. Elsevier Ltd; 2014;43: 95–104. pmid:24703175
  12. 12. Driskell JE, Salas E. Group decision making under stress. J Appl Psychol. 1991;76: 473–478. Available: http://psycnet.apa.org/journals/apl/76/3/473/
  13. 13. Buckert M, Oechssler J, Schwieren C. Imitation under stress. J Econ Behav Organ. 2017;139: 252–266.
  14. 14. Henrich J. The Secret of Our Success: How Culture is Driving Human Evolution, Domesticating Our Species, and Making Us Smarter. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press; 2016.
  15. 15. Rendell L, Fogarty L, Hoppitt WJE, Morgan TJH, Webster MM, Laland KN. Cognitive culture: theoretical and empirical insights into social learning strategies. Trends Cogn Sci. Elsevier Ltd; 2011;15: 68–76. pmid:21215677
  16. 16. Raafat RM, Chater N, Frith C. Herding in humans. Trends Cogn Sci. Elsevier Science; 2009;13: 420–428. Available: http://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/S1364661309001703
  17. 17. Avery CN, Zemsky P. Multidimensional Uncertainty and Herd Behavior in Financial Markets. Am Econ Rev. 1998;88: 724–748. Available: http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:aea:aecrev:v:88:y:1998:i:4:p:724-48
  18. 18. Park A, Sabourian H. Herding and contrarian behavior in financial markets. Econometrica. 2011;79: 973–1026. Available: http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.3982/ECTA8602/abstract
  19. 19. Sharma S, Bikhchandani S. Herd Behavior in Financial Markets—A Review [Internet]. International Monetary Fund; 2000. http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:imf:imfwpa:00/48
  20. 20. Hirshleifer D, Hong Teoh S. Herd Behaviour and Cascading in Capital Markets: a Review and Synthesis. Eur Financ Manag. Blackwell Publishing Ltd; 2003;9: 25–66.
  21. 21. Hott C. Herding behavior in asset markets. J Financ Stab. 2009;5: 35–56.
  22. 22. Choi N, Skiba H. Institutional Herding in International Markets. J Bank Financ. Elsevier B.V.; 2015;55: 246–259.
  23. 23. Huang J-HJ, Chen Y-FY. Herding in online product choice. Psychol Mark. Wiley Subscription Services, Inc., A Wiley Company; 2006;23: 413–428.
  24. 24. Chen M, Ma Q, Li M, Wang X. The Neural and Psychological Basis of Herding in Purchasing Books Online: An Event-Related Potential Study. Cyberpsychology, Behav Soc Netw. 2010;13: 7. pmid:20557253
  25. 25. Bursztyn L, Ederer F, Ferman B, Yuchtman N. Understanding Mechanisms Underlying Peer Effects: Evidence From a Field Experiment on Financial Decisions. Econometrica. 2014;82: 1273–1301.
  26. 26. Celen B, Kariv S, Schotter A. An Experimental Test of Advice and Social Learning. Manage Sci. 2010;56: 1687–1701.
  27. 27. Schotter A, Sopher B. Social Learning and Coordination Conventions in Intergenerational Games : An Experimental Study. J Polit Econ. 2003;111: 498–529.
  28. 28. Deutsch M, Gerard HB, Deutsch M, Gerard HB. A study of normative and informational social influences upon individual judgment. J Abnorm Soc Psychol. 1955;51: 629–636.
  29. 29. Baddeley M. Herding, social influence and economic decision-making: socio-psychological and neuroscientific analyses. Philos Trans R Soc Lond B Biol Sci. 2009/12/23. 2010;365: 281–90. pmid:20026466
  30. 30. Baddeley M, Pillas D, Christopoulos Y, Schultz W, Tobler PN. Herding And Social Pressure In Trading Tasks: A Behavioural Analysis. Cambridge Work Pap Econ. Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge; 2007;No. 730. http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:cam:camdae:0730
  31. 31. Asch SE. Effects of group pressure upon the modification and distortion of judgments. In: Guetzkow H, editor. Groups, Leadership, and Men. Carnegie Press; 1951. pp. 177–190. citeulike-article-id:975612
  32. 32. Sanfey AG. Social decision-making: insights from game theory and neuroscience. Science. 2007;318: 598–602. pmid:17962552
  33. 33. Baddeley M, Burke CJ, Schultz W, Tobler PN. Impacts of personality on herding in financial decision-making [Internet]. Cambridge Working Papers in Economics. Cambridge: Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge; 2010. http://ideas.repec.org/p/cam/camdae/1006.html
  34. 34. Summers D, Taliaferro JD, Fletcher D. Judgment policy and interpersonal learning. Behav Sci. 1970;15: 514–521.
  35. 35. Steinmann DO. The Effects of Cognitive Feedback and Task Complexity in Multiple-Cue Probability Learning. Organ Behav Hum Perform. 1976;15: 168–179.
  36. 36. Offerman T, Sonnemans J. Learning by experience and learning by imitating successful others. J Econ Behav Organ. 1998;34: 559–575.
  37. 37. Bikhchandani S, Hirshleifer DA, Welch I. A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades. J Polit Econ. 1992;100: 992–1026.
  38. 38. Welch I. Sequential Sales, Learning and Cascades. J Finance. 1992;47: 695–732.
  39. 39. Banerjee AV. A Simple Model of Herd Behavior. Q J Econ. 1992;107: 797–817.
  40. 40. Goeree JK, Palfrey TR, Rogers BW. Social learning with private and common values. Econ Theory. Springer Berlin / Heidelberg; 2006;28: 245–264.
  41. 41. Cao HH, Hirshleifer DA. Conversation, Observational Learning, and Informational Cascades. Dice Cent Work Pap. 2000;No. 2001–5.
  42. 42. Anderson LR, Holt CA. Information cascades in the laboratory. Am Econ Rev. 1997;87: 847–862. Available: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.2307/2951328
  43. 43. Anderson LR, Holt CA. Information Cascade Experiments. In: Plott CR, Smith VL, editors. Elsevier; 2008. pp. 335–343. http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:eee:expchp:2-39
  44. 44. Goeree JK, Palfrey TR, Rogers BW, McKelvey RD. Self-Correcting Information Cascades. Rev Econ Stud. Blackwell Publishing Ltd; 2007;74: 733–762.
  45. 45. Cipriani M, Guarino A. Herd Behavior in Financial Markets: An Experiment with Financial Market Professionals. J Eur Econ Assoc. 2009;7: 206–233. Available: http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:tpr:jeurec:v:7:y:2009:i:1:p:206-233
  46. 46. Kahneman D, Tversky A. The Concept of Probability in Psychological Experiments. Cogn Psychol. 1972;3: 430–454.
  47. 47. Grether DM. Bayes’ Rule as a Descriptive Model: The Representativeness Heuristic. Q J Econ. 1980;95: 537–557.
  48. 48. Grether DM. Testing Bayes rule and the representativeness heuristic : Some experimental evidence. J Econ Behav Organ. 1992;17: 31–57.
  49. 49. Charness G, Levin D. When optimal choices feel wrong: A laboratory study of Bayesian updating, complexity, and affect. Am Econ Rev. 2005;95: 1300–1309.
  50. 50. Charness G, Dave C. Games and Economic Behavior Confirmation bias with motivated beliefs. Games Econ Behav. Elsevier Inc.; 2017;104: 1–23.
  51. 51. El-gamal MA, Grether DM. Are People Bayesian? Uncovering Behavioral Strategies. J Am Stat Assoc. 1995;90: 1137–1145.
  52. 52. Achtziger A, Alós-Ferrer C. Fast or Rational? A response-times study of Bayesian updating. Manage Sci. 2014;60: 923–938.
  53. 53. Anderson LR, Holt CA. Classroom Games: Information Cascades. J Econ Perspect. 1996;10: 187–193. Available: http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:aea:jecper:v:10:y:1996:i:4:p:187-93
  54. 54. Dinse HR, Kattenstroth JC, Lenz M, Tegenthoff M, Wolf OT. The stress hormone cortisol blocks perceptual learning in humans. Psychoneuroendocrinology. Elsevier Ltd; 2017;77: 63–67. pmid:28024270
  55. 55. Petzold A, Plessow F, Goschke T, Kirschbaum C. Stress reduces use of negative feedback in a feedback-based learning task. Behav Neurosci. 2010;124: 248–55. pmid:20364884
  56. 56. Costa JPT, McCrae RR. Normal Personality Assessment in Clinical Practice: The NEO Personality Inventory. Psychol Assess. 1992;4: 5–13. Available: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/B6WYX-46VD04F-2/2/430de88263303f8e481e3dac5a7a52b7
  57. 57. Goldberg LR, Johnson JA, Eber HW, Hogan R, Ashton MC, Cloninger CR, et al. The international personality item pool and the future of public-domain personality measures. J Res Pers. 2006;40: 84–96.
  58. 58. Jackson DN. JPI-R: Jackson Personality Inventory, Revised. Sigma Assesment Systems, Incorporated; 1983.
  59. 59. Dickerson SS, Kemeny ME. Acute Stressors and Cortisol Responses: A Theoretical Integration and Synthesis of Laboratory Research. Psychol Bull. 2004;130: 355–391. Available: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0033290904009451 pmid:15122924
  60. 60. Goldstein DS, McEwen BS. Allostasis, Homeostats, and the Nature of Stress. Stress. 2002;5: 55–58. pmid:12171767
  61. 61. Joëls M, Baram TZ. The neuro-symphony of stress. Nat Rev Neurosci. 2009;10: 459–466. pmid:19339973
  62. 62. Kudielka BM, Hellhammer DH, Wüst S. Why do we respond so differently? Reviewing determinants of human salivary cortisol responses to challenge. Psychoneuroendocrinology. 2009;34: 2–18. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.psyneuen.2008.10.004 pmid:19041187
  63. 63. McEwen BS. Physiology and neurobiology of stress and adaptation: central role of the brain. Physiol Rev. 2007;87: 873–904. pmid:17615391
  64. 64. Everly GS, Lating JM. A Clinical Guide to the Treatment of the Human Stress Response. New York, New York, USA: Springer; 2013.
  65. 65. Ganster DC, Rosen CC. Work Stress and Employee Health: A Multidisciplinary Review. J Manage. 2013;39: 1085–1122.
  66. 66. von Dawans B, Kirschbaum C, Heinrichs M. The Trier Social Stress Test for Groups (TSST-G): A new research tool for controlled simultaneous social stress exposure in a group format. Psychoneuroendocrinology. Elsevier Ltd; 2011;36: 514–22. pmid:20843608
  67. 67. Kirschbaum C, Pirke K, Hellhammer DH. The “Trier Social Stress Test”—A Tool for Investigating Psychobiological Stress Responses in a Laboratory Setting. Neuropsychobiology. 1993;28: 76–81. Available: http://www.karger.com/DOI/10.1159/000119004 pmid:8255414
  68. 68. Goh J, Pfeffer J, Zenios SA. The Relationship Between Workplace Stressors and Mortality and Health Costs in the United States. Manage Sci. 2015; http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2014.2115
  69. 69. Kemeny ME. The Psychobiology of Stress. Curr Dir Psychol Sci. 2003;12: 124–129.
  70. 70. Allen AP, Kennedy PJ, Cryan JF, Dinan TG, Clarke G. Biological and psychological markers of stress in humans: Focus on the Trier Social Stress Test. Neurosci Biobehav Rev. Elsevier Ltd; 2014;38: 94–124. pmid:24239854
  71. 71. Cannon WB. The Wisdom of the Body. Am J Med Sci. 1932;184: 864.
  72. 72. Bracha HS. Freeze, flight, fight, fright, faint: adaptationist perspectives on the acute stress response spectrum. CNS Spectr. 2004;9: 679. pmid:15337864
  73. 73. Boyce WT, Ellis BJ. Biological sensitivity to context: I. An evolutionary—developmental theory of the origins and functions of stress reactivity. Dev Psychopathol. 2005;17: 271–301. pmid:16761546
  74. 74. Porcelli AJ, Delgado MR. Acute Stress Modulates Risk Taking in Financial Decision Making. Psychol Sci. 2009;20: 278–283. pmid:19207694
  75. 75. Leder J, Häusser JA, Mojzisch A. Exploring the underpinnings of impaired strategic decision-making under stress. J Econ Psychol. Elsevier B.V.; 2015;
  76. 76. Maier SU, Makwana AB, Hare TA. Acute Stress Impairs Self-Control in Goal-Directed Choice by Altering Multiple Functional Connections within the Brain’s Decision Circuits. Neuron. Elsevier Inc.; 2015;87: 621–631. pmid:26247866
  77. 77. Miller EK. The prefrontal cortex and cognitive control. Nat Rev Neurosci. 2000;1: 59–65. pmid:11252769
  78. 78. Miller EK, Cohen JD. An integrative theory of prefrontal cortex function. Annu Rev Neurosci. Annual Reviews 4139 El Camino Way, PO Box 10139, Palo Alto, CA 94303–0139, USA; 2001;24: 167–202. pmid:11283309
  79. 79. Gazzaniga MS, Ivry RB, Mangun GR. Cognitive Neuroscience: The Biology of the Mind. New York: W. W. Norton & Company; Third Edition; 2008.
  80. 80. Klucharev V, Hytönen K, Rijpkema M, Smidts A, Fernández G. Reinforcement learning signal predicts social conformity. Neuron. 2009;61: 140–51. pmid:19146819
  81. 81. Klucharev V, Munneke MAM, Smidts A, Fernández G. Downregulation of the posterior medial frontal cortex prevents social conformity. J Neurosci. 2011;31: 11934–11940. pmid:21849554
  82. 82. Burke CJ, Tobler PN, Baddeley M, Schultz W. Neural mechanisms of observational learning. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A. 2010;107: 14431–6. pmid:20660717
  83. 83. Lighthall NR, Mather M, Gorlick MA. Acute stress increases sex differences in risk seeking in the balloon analogue risk task. PLoS One. Public Library of Science; 2009;4: e6002. pmid:19568417
  84. 84. Pabst S, Brand M, Wolf OT. Stress effects on framed decisions: there are differences for gains and losses. Front Behav Neurosci. 2013;7. pmid:24130523
  85. 85. Sokol-Hessner P, Raio CM, Gottesman SP, Lackovic SF, Phelps EA. Acute stress does not affect risky monetary decision-making. Neurobiol Stress. Elsevier Inc; 2016;5: 19–25. pmid:27981193
  86. 86. Goette L, Bendahan S, Thoresen J, Hollis F, Sandi C. Stress pulls us apart : Trait anxiety modulates self-confidence under stress. Psychoneuroendocrinology. Elsevier Ltd; 2015;54: 115–123.
  87. 87. Goldberg LR. International Personality Item Pool: A Scientific Collaboratory for the Development of Advanced Measures of Personality Traits and Other Individual Differences [Internet]. 2010. http://ipip.ori.org/
  88. 88. Delfino A, Marengo L, Ploner M. I did it your way. An experimental investigation of peer effects in investment choices. J Econ Psychol. Elsevier B.V.; 2016;54: 113–123.
  89. 89. Artinger F, Exadaktylos F, Koppel H, Sääksvuori L. Applying quadratic scoring rule transparently in multiple choice settings: A note. Jena Econ Res Pap. 2010;021.
  90. 90. Andersen S, Fountain J, Harrison GW, Rutström EE. Estimating subjective probabilities. J Risk Uncertain. 2014;48: 207–229.
  91. 91. Schlag KH, Tremewan J, van der Weele JJ. A penny for your thoughts : a survey of methods for eliciting beliefs. Exp Econ. 2015;18: 457–490.
  92. 92. Holt CA, Laury SK. Risk Aversion and Incentive Effects. Am Econ Rev. American Economic Association; 2002;92: 1644–1655. Available: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3083270
  93. 93. Armantier O, Treich N. Subjective Probabilities in Games : An Application to the Overbidding Puzzle. Int Econ Rev (Philadelphia). 2009;50: 1079–1102.
  94. 94. Dohmen T, Falk A, Huffman D, Sunde U. Are risk aversion and impatience related to cognitive ability? Am Econ Rev. 2010;100: 1238–1260. Available: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1146778
  95. 95. Fischbacher U. Z-TREE: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp Econ. 2007;10: 171–178. Available: http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:kap:expeco:v:10:y:2007:i:2:p:171-178
  96. 96. Cahlíková J, Cingl L. Risk preferences under acute stress. Exp Econ. Springer US; 2017;20: 209–236.
  97. 97. Greiner B. An online recruitment system for economic experiments. In: Kremer K, Macho V, editors. Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen GWDG Bericht. Göttingen: Gesellschaft fur Wissenschaftliche Datenverarbeitung; 2004.
  98. 98. Nicolson N. Measurement of cortisol. In: Leucken LJ G L.C., editor. Handbook of physiological research methods in health psychology. SAGE Publications; 2007. pp. 37–73.
  99. 99. Weizsäcker G. Do We Follow Others when We Should? A Simple Test of Rational Expectations. Am Econ Rev. 2010;100: 2340–2360.
  100. 100. Huber RE, Klucharev V, Rieskamp J. Neural correlates of informational cascades: brain mechanisms of social influence on belief updating. Scan. 2015;10: 589–597. pmid:24974396
  101. 101. Miller R, Plessow F, Kirschbaum C, Stalder T. Classification criteria for distinguishing cortisol responders from nonresponders to psychosocial stress: evaluation of salivary cortisol pulse detection in panel designs. Psychosom Med. 2013;75: 832–40. pmid:24184845
  102. 102. Steyer R, Schwenkmezger P, Notz P, Eid M. MDBF-Mehrdimensionaler Befindlichkeitsfragebogen. Göttingen: Hogrefe; 1997.
  103. 103. Hellhammer DH, Wüst S, Kudielka BM. Salivary cortisol as a biomarker in stress research. Psychoneuroendocrinology. 2009;34: 163–171. pmid:19095358
  104. 104. Kudielka BM, Buske-Kirschbaum A, Hellhammer DH, Kirschbaum C. HPA axis responses to laboratory psychosocial stress in healthy elderly adults, younger adults, and children: impact of age and gender. Psychoneuroendocrinology. 2004;29: 83–98. pmid:14575731
  105. 105. Haushofer J, Cornelisse S, Seinstra M, Fehr E, Joëls M, Kalenscher T. No effects of psychosocial stress on intertemporal choice. PLoS One. 2013;8: e78597. pmid:24250800
  106. 106. Salop SCS. Evaluating uncertain evidence with Sir Thomas Bayes: A note for teachers. J Econ Perspect. American Economic Association; 1987;1: 155–159. Available: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.2307/1942953
  107. 107. Kahneman D, Tversky A. On the psychology of prediction. Psychol Rev. 1973;80: 237. Available: http://psycnet.apa.org/journals/rev/80/4/237/
  108. 108. Faul F, Erdfelder E, Buchner A, Lang A-G. Statistical power analyses using G*Power 3.1: tests for correlation and regression analyses. Behav Res Methods. 2009;41: 1149–60. pmid:19897823
  109. 109. Cohen J. Statistical power analysis for the behavioral sciences. Hillsdale, New Jersey: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates; 1988.
  110. 110. Haushofer J, Shapiro J. The Short-Term Impact of Unconditional Cash Transfers to the Poor: Experimental Evidence from Kenya. Q J Econ. 2016;131: 1973–2042.
  111. 111. Porcelli AJ, Lewis AH, Delgado MR. Acute stress influences neural circuits of reward processing. Front Neurosci. 2012;6: 157. pmid:23125822
  112. 112. Buckert M, Schwieren C, Kudielka BM, Fiebach CJ. Acute stress affects risk taking but not ambiguity aversion. Front Neurosci. 2014;8: 82. pmid:24834024
  113. 113. Buser T, Dreber A, Mollerstrom J. The impact of stress on tournament entry. Exp Econ. 2017;20: 506–530. pmid:28553158
  114. 114. Zhong S, Shalev I, Koh D, Ebstein RP, Chew SH. Competitiveness and Stress. Int Econ Rev. 2017; 1–50. Available: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2717459
  115. 115. Haushofer J, Jang C. Stress and Temporal Discounting : Do Domains Matter? mimeo. 2015;
  116. 116. Haushofer J, Prachi J, Musau A, Ndetei D. Effects of Stress on Economic Choice. Work Pap. 2018;
  117. 117. Pabst S, Brand M, Wolf OT. Stress and decision making: a few minutes make all the difference. Behav Brain Res. Elsevier B.V.; 2013;250: 39–45. pmid:23643690