Skip to main content
Advertisement
Browse Subject Areas
?

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here.

  • Loading metrics

A Geometrical Perspective for the Bargaining Problem

Abstract

A new treatment to determine the Pareto-optimal outcome for a non-zero-sum game is presented. An equilibrium point for any game is defined here as a set of strategy choices for the players, such that no change in the choice of any single player will increase the overall payoff of all the players. Determining equilibrium for multi-player games is a complex problem. An intuitive conceptual tool for reducing the complexity, via the idea of spatially representing strategy options in the bargaining problem is proposed. Based on this geometry, an equilibrium condition is established such that the product of their gains over what each receives is maximal. The geometrical analysis of a cooperative bargaining game provides an example for solving multi-player and non-zero-sum games efficiently.

Introduction

1.1 Scope and Objective

Pareto-optimality is concerned with the logical analysis of optimizing a set of strategies in a real life situation involving the interaction of more than one individual, that can be mathematically modeled as a game [1],[2]. The payoff in a game can be non-measurable psychological parameters such as utility, prestige, desire, security level, or measurable quantities that serve as a common medium of exchange. Some simple games, such as the bargaining problem [3], are known as non-zero-sum games and the players try to achieve a win-win situation. The game “paper-rock-scissors” is a zero-sum game, since the payoff to the winner of a single instance of the game is equal to the loss of the other player. In any game, there exist choices of strategies that may be adopted to maximize sum total payoff. For a generic n-player game, there is always a solution for the optimal strategy for each person. This strategy guarantees their average payoff or loss is maximized or minimized under the assumption that the opposing player also uses an optimal strategy. This solution corresponds to the equilibrium point (EP) of the game, and may be non-deterministic, in that the optimal choice of strategy to use in any given play of the game is chosen randomly according to a probability distribution over all possible strategy choices.

In this paper, the focus is on the analysis of non-zero-sum games. Another classic non-zero-sum game is “the Prisoner's Dilemma” [4],[5],[6] but it pertains to a non-cooperative one. More practical games typically involve multiple players in areas of economics [7] and mathematical biology [8],[9],[10]. The computation of EP increases significantly in complexity for multi-player, multi-strategy and non-zero-sum cooperative games [11].

The notion of an EP is the key ingredient in a game, and is what we aim to obtain. There may be more than one EP; and for a two-person zero-sum game, it is simply the set of all pairs of opposing good strategies [12] whereas for a non-zero-sum game, it consists of pairs of reinforcing good strategies. The approach to solving non-zero-sum cooperative games, for the case of two players, can be better understood if the utility gains of all possible actions are computed and plotted as a set of alternatives on a two-dimensional graph. The convex point at the vertex of the possible set of solutions corresponds to the optimal utility gain for both persons. For an n-players game, this treatment can be extrapolated to a set of alternatives on a multi-dimensional graph.

1.2 Theory of Utility

The theory of utility can be observed in many games. In the simplest bargaining scenario presented by Nash, two cooperative individuals have a certain list of goods to barter trade [12]. This simple example can be extended to other situations of bargaining, such as employer and union negotiation, or to that of two villages with different resources and an aim of optimizing economic benefit in trade. As an example, we present a primitive scenario whereby two villages, hereby labeled as Villages 1 and 2, are involved in barter trading of specific goods. Village 1 relies on coal production as the main source of its revenue. Village 2 is assumed to have abundant cattle production but has insufficient coal resources. We make a further assumption that cattle are of lesser abundance, and hence these goods enjoy a higher value compared to coal. If the two villages concentrate on their strengths of production individually, and perform trading of the goods that have different utilities to each party, a point of equilibrium in trade will be reached at a certain point of time. Coal will naturally be more valued within Village 2 due to limitation, but a huge quantity of cattle will essentially not be produced if greater efforts are aimed at producing coal. It is better to trade cattle for coal since this is a less expensive alternative in terms of value that pertains to the good. Village 1 that trades coal for cattle perceives and thinks likewise. A certain equilibrium trading quantity of the two goods can be reached in a mutual trade agreement depending on the utility value of goods to each village. This equilibrium corresponds to the payoff of the two villages.

From a psychological perspective, the utility value of an item to an individual is dictated by state of mind at a particular time. It varies according to the events that occurred to the person previously, and is evidently a random psychological parameter. Analogously, the security level of performing a specific task can also be linked to this utility value. In practice, we are all dictated by this value in determining our actions or performing any type of task assigned to us. For instance, a shopper may decide to buy a tin of cookies instead of a box of chocolates because the cookies appeal more to that person in terms of taste, price or aesthetic property, and hence, has a higher utility value in comparison. This utility value may change when the shopper tires of eating cookies after a few days and desires a taste of chocolate the next time. Desire or utility of a grocery to a shopper may also vary based on available quantity at its time of acquisition.

It is difficult to construct a perfect model of a game that is a reflection of reality. There will always be numerous outcomes to consider even for the simplest games. For example, when volumes of items are divided for exchange, its value to each player may change. There are usually too many variables such as the bargaining abilities of the players, the norms of the society, and the variation in utility of the items over time for the formal theory to be accommodated [14]. But understanding bargaining games from a simplistic perspective can assist in the study and formulation of frameworks for determining EP.

1.3 The Bargaining Problem

For the bargaining problem, we illustrate how, as a special case, the two persons can perform barter trade such that their utility gains are maximized. We assume two players - Player 1 and Player 2 who are in a position to barter goods but have no money to facilitate the exchange [12]. Bargaining theory is a generalized concept of the two-person bargaining problem. The game is a cooperative one as both players have complete information about the game; each player is fully aware of the payoff or profit for themselves and their co-players, for every possible transaction. Such games are also known as cooperative games in which all players have identical interests.

In the two-player bargaining situation, a compact convex metrical space Si of mixed strategies σi pertains to Player i, for . These mixed strategies represent the courses of action the player can take independently of the other players. The randomization process of establishing all possible strategy alternatives illustrates the possible joint courses of action by the players. This set of alternatives can be represented by a convex polytope in the plane with the dimensions of utility gains for the players. For each pair of mixed strategies (σ1, σ2) from (S1, S2), the payoffs for the deployment of these strategies are denoted by Π1(σ1, σ2) and Π2(σ1, σ2) respectively. Such payoff of each mixed strategy pair corresponds to a point in the convex polytope of the super set strategy alternatives [13].

An outcome is in equilibrium if there is no other possible agreement that allows both players to have higher payoffs simultaneously [14]. The barter trade such that maximum utility gain Gi is achieved is known as Pareto-optimal. Note that gain is the excess of payoff after bargaining over the initial payoff before strategy choices are chosen. Nash has shown that obtaining the maximum of the product of the two utility gains (G1 and G2) from the set of alternatives, known as the Nash product G1G2, will attain the Pareto-optimal solution for the bargaining situation. Pareto-optimality is a non-zero sum Nash game equilibrium point that determines the Pareto efficiency of the outcome. It is also worthwhile mentioning that there may be more than one equilibrium point, and this set of points can be defined as the equilibrium point (EP).

The combinatorial plot for this bargaining situation is illustrated in Figure 1, where the set of alternatives for all possible item exchanges is enclosed by a boundary curve. We make the assumption that at least one item is possessed by each player in the end. The super set of alternatives results in a convex polygon whereby the product of maximum utility gains is maximized at its vertex. In practice, we aim to optimize the Nash product G1G2.

thumbnail
Figure 1. Set of bargaining alternatives for two players whereby the Nash equilibrium corresponds to optimal utility gains.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.g001

The solution is a Pareto-optimal outcome, in which the joint profits by all parties are maximized. It may be worthwhile noting that the Nash equilibrium is not unique as multiple or even an infinite number of strategies that pertain to the Nash equilibria exist. In this game theoretical setup, all items are discrete, and the discreteness of the payoffs increases the complexity of attaining the solution.

1.4 Pareto-optimal Equilibrium

Based on a multi-player bargaining situation, establishing the payoff matrix containing the super set of strategy choice alternatives is computationally expensive. It is to be noted that proving the existence of the Pareto-optimal equilibrium point and finding the solution set at the equilibrium are different tasks. In general, computation of a Pareto-optimal equilibrium point in mixed strategies of a finite game poses a numerical challenge for the following reason. For multiple players, determining the Pareto-optimal equilibrium in mixed strategies amounts to solving a system of multivariate polynomial equations of high order [13] and, as a rule, does not have an explicit solution. Despite significant progress in recent years, algorithms for computing equilibrium are still not competent at solving very large games. Approximate solution methods are often the best computed solution or EP set. This forms the problem definition in our study.

The concept of representing utility of strategy executions geometrically is used to answer the fundamental question in the Pareto-optimal equilibrium solution. Obtaining information regarding the strategy options and payoffs to every player, and with respect to other players, is crucial to the computation of the Pareto-optimal EP. This information can be represented spatially in a geometrical framework. It turns out that by using the spatial game setup, the extraction of the subset of strategy alternatives from the superset can be achieved and the convergence to the Pareto-optimal solution using less computation can be obtained. Such a concept forms the main basis of this paper, and we will examine the game theoretical geometry in greater details with the support of case studies.

1.5 Representation of Utility as Geometrical Distance

The game theoretical studies by von Neumann and Morgenstern (1980) is based on the representation of all outcomes of n-player games as payoff vectors such that points exist in an n-dimensional utility space [15]. This has been a standard representation of utility space for n-person game models to date. In the spatial game model that they have created, outcomes of the games have been assumed to lie in some low-dimensional Euclidean space such that utilities to the players are defined in terms of distance from their most preferred, or ideal points [16]. Such a representation is useful for establishing outcomes that correspond to public good (all individuals obtaining benefit from the same outcome). The model assumed that utility is a decreasing function of the distance between the achieved outcome and the ideal point [17].

For example, their m-dimensional spatial game is described as a collection of n points Pi, i = 1,…,n, in m-dimensional Euclidean space Rm. Point Pi is player i's ideal point. The convex hull of the points is the Pareto-optimal set. The points of space Rm are the items in the game that we have discussed. The players are to choose among all the items in the game what they wish to own. It is assumed that a player may be most satisfied with an item at Pi, however failing to obtain that, the next possible closest item will be chosen.

The next section will focus on presenting a more refined technique for determining the Pareto-optimality of a bargaining problem for multi-players (n>2). The fundamental concepts of representing utility as a distance in space will be presented.

Methods

2.1 Geometrical Representation of Utility

Suppose the payoff value to the player of a strategy item being executed can be represented by the “item-to-player” distance, such that items of higher utility value have a higher spatial proximity. In effect, the proximity value would be the inverse of the payoff value. For two parties, if one represents all the items based on payoff value on a two-dimensional space, an equilibrium line could be drawn to assign that item to the respective player such that payoff value for both is maximized. This technique removes the need to generate the payoff gain for every single possible set of strategy execution, hence avoiding intense computational load. In fact, this method of assigning items of significance closer to the owner will effectively eliminate the consideration of all the strategy alternatives, based on the fact that the product of gain will be maximal at the location near the equilibrium line. For example, it is not a recommendable strategy to assign items of low payoff to any one player. Now, this distance-based approach is explored to derive the EP of a bargaining situation.

The convex polytope of a multi-player game can be simplified to a three dimensional spatial representation with the player-to-player distances defined to be constant as shown in Figure 2. In this approach, all items are represented as geometrical points that lie within a boundary or space enclosed by the players (labeled as 1, 2,…, n) that are presented as vertices of this spatial volume. For example, based on three players, the items will lie within an enclosed triangle. With four players, the items are enclosed by a tetrahedron with four vertices. Based on a five-player game, the positioning of items is within a space enclosed by a pyramid. In general, n number of players will result in an n-polyhedron defined by the ideal position of all players representing its vertices. The distance between player-to-player decreases as more players participate because for an item x, its normalized and relative distances to all the players (labeled as d1,x, d2,x,…, dn,x) add up to a unitary value. Therefore, the space enclosed by the polyhedron becomes smaller as the number of players increases.

thumbnail
Figure 2. Geometrical distribution of items whose cross-links represent their distances to every person in an n-player game.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.g002

2.1.1 Geometrical Distance of Item.

We introduce the following notation:

  1. ui,x represents the utility of item x to player i;
  2. di,x represents the normalized distance of item x to player i with respect to other players;

The distance of an item to the player is defined as a decreasing function of the utility. The inverse proportionality function is used. Here, the distance of item x to player i is defined to be the inverse of ui,x. Next, based on every item, its normalized distance is given by the ratio of distance for player i to the sum of distances for all players. The following equation presents the geometrical parameter as(1)

2.1.2 Prioritized Assignment of Items.

The items are arranged spatially based on their normalized distances to every player in ascending order. Here, a list of items ordered in terms of priority for player i is denoted as where(2)The normalized distance contains information regarding the priority of the item to one player with respect to the others based on the geometrical treatment presented in Section 3.1.1. The priority of an item is an indication of its value or importance to the player, and is the inverse of this normalized distance. Therefore, assigned items in terms of priority is defined here as a possession list of items in descending order of importance to a player.

Combinatorial analysis for all alternatives is computationally expensive. Assigning items of lower priorities to a player shifts the equilibrium away from the Pareto-optimality. On the contrary, assignment of items with higher priorities converge the solution set towards an EP. Assignment of items to a player by traversing them from the highest priority to the lowest one enhances computational resources. Therefore, instead of using a combinatorial technique to obtain the optimal product of gain for all players, a more efficient assignment approach based on priority of items can be applied. Items can be spatially arranged in terms of value for every player in the game. An item priority to a player is based on the normalized distance with respect to all players.

In summary, the method of assigning items focuses on considering a set of alternatives that lies close to the real solution set. In a way, it eliminates the redundant computation of alternatives that deviates from the EP. In Section 4, we demonstrate that the EP solution set lies within the reduced set of alternatives.

2.2 Basis of Convergence towards Equilibrium

It is computationally expensive to consider all bargaining alternatives from a combinatorial set. This section describes a technique for evaluating a bargaining game via item assignment to each player. It analyzes the game based on multiple cases of item assignment by taking into account one player that pertains to each case. For n players, such assignment of items is performed n times.

The utility is related to priority. Since priority is the inverse of normalized distance of a bargain item, a property that relates to the payoff per priority is introduced here. To achieve this, we will discuss this indicator from a mechanical perspective. For a mechanical lever system, the moment by weight about a point Q is defined as the product  = ||d, where d is the (perpendicular) distance between Q and the line of action L of . If is the vector from Q to any point A on L, then the moment vector of about Q is given by  = ×.

Assume two players (i{1,2}) possessing items given by x{1,…,11} such that utility is a function of importance of an item to a player and represented by its normalized distance as shown in Figure 3. Here, is assumed to be a decreasing function of . A utility-distance product of an item value (which is related to its importance in terms of payoff to the player) is based on distance d from a player spatially and in vector form. We denote this entity as, which is a function of and . For n players, using each player as a pivot point, the importance of an item can be weighing about n number of pivots such that their utility-distance product vectors have the same magnitude.

thumbnail
Figure 3. Spatial positions of items presented in x-direction and magnitudes of their utilities and utility-distance products in y-direction for two players.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.g003

From a mechanical perspective, equally spaced weights on a lever are aligned along the same direction such that the weights on the left hand side generate a collective moment that opposes the moment caused by the weights on the right. By the same concept, to maintain zero utility-distance product equilibrium, the sum of utility-distance product vectors by all the items is equally divided for the players (Figure 4). Selecting items of closer distance to the player maximizes their payoffs. Maximizing the sum of utility-distance products for every player simultaneously provides the equilibrium solution for such theoretical game using this geometrical setup.

thumbnail
Figure 4. Determination of equilibrium based on distribution of utility-distance product vectors about a pivot point for two players.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.g004

Assume that the items are analogous to equal quantity of weights on a lever system that is balanced such that(3)Consider that the utility-distance product vector of an item x about a player i from spatial vector is denoted by . A player has k items, each of value . For an ideal condition whereby all items lie in a space between two vertices representing players, and at equal distances. Here, the vector sum of utility-distance products is(4)Due to our assumption that utility decreases linearly with respect to distance, a pivot positioned at a distance of causes the vectors given by  =  to sum up to zero where(5)In practice, the vector may vary for different items. A more appropriate determination of pivot location can be based on balancing utility-distance products vectors with respect to n player, which is given by(6)In theory, utility-distance product of an item is analogous to moment of force by weights based on a lever system. By suitably locating a pivot location such that distribution of the utility-distance product vectors are uniformly positioned about a pivot, equilibrium can be achieved. This concept can effectively reduce computational load of item assignments in a multi-player game theoretical situation. The reduced set of alternatives that is determined is the solution set closer to Pareto-optimality, which forms the basis of convergence towards EP.

2.2.1 Utility-Distance Product of Item.

From Section 3.1.1, the properties utilized in our framework are ui,x, which represents the utility of item x to player i; And di,x represents the normalized distance of item x to player i with respect to other players. We also define the utility-distance product of the item x from distance di,x for the player i.

The utility-distance product for an item denoted as x, is computed by multiplying the normalized distance of that item with its corresponding payoff value for player i such that(7)

2.2.2 Pareto-Optimality Based on Geometry.

For k items, every item x is prioritized based on normalized distances di,x from player i to form a list given by Pi (Equation (2)). Here, Pi,x represents an item x in the order of priority for a player. Cumulative values of utility-distance products are determined based on the list , which consists of k items in descending order of priority. Here, corresponds to an item at position x in this list. The possession list of every player is initialized to null. We define as the items after bargaining in one strategy set for the player i respectively. The items are traversed in the high to low priority direction, and assigned to player i's possession list until the cumulative utility-distance products equals . Recall that is the quantification of utility-distance products up to a point of equilibrium (Equation (6)). The item that corresponds to the pivot location is hereby denoted as . We note that may not lie exactly at the pivoting point. Mathematically,(8)(9)(10)Depending on the nature of the game, different interpretations of an EP can be made. If the items are assumed to be discrete, then assignment of items up to for player i forms a strategy set σi. Repeating such an assignment for n players forms n strategy sets, {σ1, σ2, …, σn}, whereby this n-tuple of strategies forms the negotiation set of the game. Pareto-optimal equilibrium is attained when no player can increase their payoff any more by changing strategy and assuming that none of the other players is going to change their strategies.

Results

3.1 Definition of n-player Bargaining Case Studies

The multi-player bargaining scenario is a cooperative game; information is shared and every member trades in such a manner that their strategies will mutually benefit all the players in the game. The existence of a transferable commodity is assumed to be present. From the bargaining perspective, the items of transaction are analogous to the strategy choices, and the utility gain of a typical transaction is analogous to the payoff of executing a particular strategy. The proposed case studies will only work for relative payoff values for the players. In this paper, we denote the payoff as a function of item x, whereby Πi () for player i and k number of items. To limit the EP to only one solution (assuming that no two or more items are similar), the optimality condition is defined in this paper as a function of the product of gains.

We have assumed that the items are being assigned based on non-initialized possession lists. The utility gains are positive provided that the initial total payoff value of any one list does not exceed that of the created solution possession list. Assume that the initial payoff for Player i is Πi′. Then for n players, the product of payoff gain is given by(11)For all players i such that Πi is greater than Πi′, positive payoff by all persons is achieved. Negative gain situations can be prevented by first assigning the items starting from those with higher priorities in the ordered list based on normalized distances until their aggregate payoff values equal or exceed the initial payoff value. The remaining items are then assigned again starting from the one with the next highest priority.

3.2 Two-player Bargaining Game (n = 2)

A primitive setup of a two-village bargaining problem is defined here, in which Villages 1 and 2 possess goods to perform barter trade (Table 1), with the objective of maximizing the gains.

The initial values of the utility sums for the villages are(12)In Table 2, based on Equations (1) and (7), the normalized distances and utility-distance product for Villages 1 and 2 (denoted as i = 1 and 2 respectively) are presented.

thumbnail
Table 2. Utility-distance product of goods for Villages (i{1, 2}).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.t002

The equilibrium condition is(13)The cumulative utility-distance products of the goods are listed in Table 3 in terms of priority for Village 1 that is ordered from left to right. For Village 2, the cumulative operation starts in the opposite direction. The geometrical treatment gives as Mineral (x = 3). An EP set is determined here: all goods of higher priority to Village 1 up till before are assigned to this village and the rest of the goods pertain to Village 2. Based on the possession lists of the two players, we obtain(14)The same scenario in a two-village game is considered but discussions of special situations such as negative utility gains are established using a different data set. An example using a data set with a significantly different total utility values between the two players can illustrate the problem.

thumbnail
Table 3. Cumulative utility-distance products of goods for Villages (i{1, 2}).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.t003

It is assumed that Villages 1 and 2 have goods in their initial possession list with a difference in sum of utilities for initial goods of possession. If one village has a final utility sum that is lower than the initial total utility value, then the product of utility gain is negative. This usually occurs when one village has a significantly larger possession list in comparison with the other one. Let us consider the case of having a larger difference in sum of utilities for initial goods. Assume that Villages 1 and 2 have different goods as shown by Table 4.

The initial values of the utility sums for the villages are(15)Bargaining, based on the assumption that villages have initial possession lists, results in(16)The proposed approach can present the utility gains with optimality by assigning of goods a priori. Referring to the priority ordering, and listing the cumulative utility values for Villages 1 and 2, some of the goods can be assigned a priori in Table 5 before determination of using Table 6.

thumbnail
Table 5. Cumulative utilities of goods for Villages (i{1,2}).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.t005

thumbnail
Table 6. Cumulative utility-distance products of unassigned goods.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.t006

Here, a possession list that pertains to Village 1 comprises of Iron, Salt, Steel, Wine, and Mineral, while that of Village 2 consists of Coal only. The remaining goods are Cattle, Oil, and Gas. These goods can be assigned by determining the utility-distance products for Village 1 and 2 to give as Oil. The utilities and gains are(17)In practice, we create an initial list of goods and then assign the remaining ones. This can save computation of the utility-distance products for the goods of bargain that can be initialized a priori.

3.3 Three-player Bargaining Game (n = 3)

The geometrical framework for a bargaining game by two players can be generalized to n players. In general, this method facilitates an ordered priority list for every player when determining the equilibrium point. This concept can be extended to the calculation of bargaining solution for multiple villages involved in the exchange of their produce limited by our assumptions. As only one village needs to be considered at a time for good assignment, we are able to determine the assignment of bargaining goods towards attaining EP and maximization of gains.

Suppose that three villages (i{1,2,3}) is involved in a bargaining game (n = 3). The normalized distances and utility-distance products of initially possessed goods are presented in Table 7. The geometrical representation of the goods is illustrated in Figure 5, which shows the utility values of the goods for each village spatially on a two-dimensional plane. Figure 6 shows the utility-distance product of each item to the respective player. The goods are positioned at various loci of the enclosed triangle. Here, the locus is based on the distances from item to each player vertex.

thumbnail
Figure 5. Geometrical distribution of goods for Villages (i{1,2,3}).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.g005

thumbnail
Figure 6. Geometrical distribution of goods presented with magnitudes of utility and utility-distance product for Villages (i{1,2,3}).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.g006

thumbnail
Table 7. Utility-distance product of goods for Villages (i{1,2,3}).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.t007

The initial values of the utility sums for village are(18)An equilibrium condition can be determined by(19)From Table 8, we deduced that  = Wine,  = Milk, and  = Steel. Here, goods assigned to Villages 1, 2, and 3 are {Iron, Salt, Steel, and Wine}, {Coal, Orange, Timber, Cattle, and Milk}, and {Oil, Orange, Gas, Mineral, and Steel} respectively. The Orange entity is assigned simultaneously to Village 2 and Village 3's possession lists. And Steel appears in Village 1 and Village 3's possessions. Since Steel has a higher priority to Village 1 than Village 3, and the same condition occurs for the case of Village 2 versus Village 3, during the assignment of Orange, Village 1 and Village 3 are assigned Steel and Orange respectively.

thumbnail
Table 8. Cumulative utility-distance products of goods for Villages (i{1,2,3}).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010331.t008

The result of assignment is displayed in Table 9. Here, we obtain(20)The geometrical approach in predicting the Pareto-optimal solution set for multiple players (n = 3) demonstrates that equilibrium can be attained by balancing the utility-distance product values of all goods among the three villages. Payoff in terms of utility is arbitrarily set to present a barter trade scenario here as a case study. In practice, the game is based on an arbitrary number of players in order to demonstrate the fundamental principles of the technique without incurring further complexities that may arise if more players are used.

Discussion

The solution to a bargaining problem is reflected as the Pareto-optimal EP of the set of bargaining alternatives. The combination of possible sets escalates when the number of strategy choices and players increases. To reduce the number of alternatives considered in a combinatorial set, the concept of using spatial distance to represent the significance of the item to the player in a non-zero-sum game can be implemented.

To allow assignment of items while considering only one player at a time, the concept of using the geometrical distance to represent utility of items is introduced. Then, this technique can extract a smaller set of alternatives from the super set of strategy alternatives and enables the Pareto-optimal EP to be obtained from this reduced set. The attainment of the solution is determined by the nature of the strategy choices. Instead of using multivariate polynomial functions, the geometrical approach reduces the computational expenses involved in determining EP. For instance, the concept of shifting the bargaining outcome towards Pareto-optimal equilibrium is by geometrically positioning items of higher priority to one player with respect to the others using a shorter relative distance.

Spatial representation of items based on their utility can be used to derive the Pareto-optimal EP in non-zero-sum games. This method relies on the concept of spatial distribution of items respective to its level of significance to the players involved. The efficiency of calculating the EP for n- players in a game has been greatly improved, but there are a few limitations that have yet to be resolved such as the definition of an optimality equation in the bargaining game. This is a very important tool as the EP of a large-scale game is the main objective of almost all the real games in the world.

Author Contributions

Conceived and designed the experiments: KKLW. Performed the experiments: KKLW. Analyzed the data: KKLW. Contributed reagents/materials/analysis tools: KKLW. Wrote the paper: KKLW.

References

  1. 1. Rasmusen E (2001) Games & information: an introduction to game theory, 3rd edition. Blackwell Publishers Ltd, Oxford.
  2. 2. Khan MA, Sun Y (2002) Noncooperative games with many players,. In: Aumann RJ, Hart S, editors. in: Handbook of Game Theory, vol. 3. North-Holland, Chapter 46.
  3. 3. Nash JF (1950) The bargaining problem, Econometrica. Econometric Society 18(2): 155–162.
  4. 4. Nash JF (1951) Non-cooperative games. Ann of Math 54: 286–295.
  5. 5. Iqbal A, Cheon T, Abbott D (2008) Probabilistic analysis of three-player symmetric quantum games played using the Einstein-Podolsky-Rosen-Bohm setting. Physics Letters A 372(44): 6564–6577.
  6. 6. Rapoport A, Chammah A, Dwyer J, Gyr J (2007) Three-person non-zero-sum nonnegotiable games. Behavioral Science 7(1): 38–58.
  7. 7. Aumann RJ, Hart S (2002) Handbook of Game Theory. North-Holland..
  8. 8. Broom M, Cannings C, Vickers GT (1997) Multi-player matrix games. Bulletin of Mathematical Biology 59: 931–952.
  9. 9. Broom M (2003) The use of multiplayer game theory in the modeling of biological populations. Comments on Theoretical Biology 8: 103–123.
  10. 10. Hofbauer J, Sigmund K (1988) Evolutionary games and population dynamics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
  11. 11. Daskalakis C, Papadimitriou CH (2005) Three-player games are hard. Electronic Colloquium on Computational Complexity, Report No. 139.
  12. 12. Nash JF (1997) Essays on Game Theory. Edward Elgar Publishing Company, USA, ISBN: 9781858984261.
  13. 13. Viossat Y (2006) The geometry of Nash equilibria and correlated equilibria and a generalization of zero-sum games. Working Paper Series in Economics and Finance 641, Stockholm School of Economics.
  14. 14. Davis MD (1997) Game theory: a nontechnical introduction. Dover Publications, USA, ISBN: 9780486296722.
  15. 15. Von Neumann J, Morgenstern O (1980) Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton University Press, ISBN: 9780691041834.
  16. 16. Owen G (1995) Game theory. Academic Press Inc, USA, 3rd edition, ISBN: 0125311516.
  17. 17. Baron R, Durieu J, Haller H, Solal P (2002) Finding a Nash equilibrium in spatial games is an NP-complete problem. Discussion paper 02-19. University of Copenhagen.